Improving Access to Savings through Mobile Money: Experimental Evidence from Smallholder Farmers in Mozambique* Catia Batista†, Pedro C. Vicente‡, and Dean Yang§ December 2016 Abstract: Investment in improved agricultural inputs is infrequent for smallholder farmers in Africa. One barrier may be limited access to formal savings. We designed and conducted a field experiment in rural Mozambique that randomized access to a savings account through mobile money to a sample of smallholder farmers. All subjects were given access to mobile money and information about fertilizer use. We also randomized whether closest farming friends were targeted by the same intervention. We find that the savings account increased savings, the probability of fertilizer use, by 31-36 pp, the use of other agricultural inputs. We show that the savings account increased household expenditures, in particular non-frequent ones. We also suggest that the network intervention decreased social pressure to share resources and that the savings account protected farmers against this network pressure. JEL Codes: D14, D85. Keywords: Mobile Money, Savings, Agriculture, Smallholder Farmers, Social Networks, Field Experiment, Mozambique, Africa. * We wish to thank Simone Bertoli and Maya Shankar for helpful suggestions on the analysis of this paper. We are also grateful to Luke Crowley, Matilde Grácio, Diogo Mendes, and Guilherme Rodrigues for excellent field coordination. We thank seminar participants at CERDI, CSAE, IGC, and NOVAFRICA for useful comments. We are particularly grateful to Carteira Móvel, Mcel, and the International Growth Centre for fruitful collaboration in Mozambique. Nadean Szafman and his team, and Mindy Hernandez offered important inputs to this project for which we are most thankful. Finally, we would like to extend an appreciative word to the group of enumerators with whom we worked. IRB approval was secured from Innovations for Poverty Action. We wish to acknowledge financial support from ATAI and USAID. All errors are our responsibility. † Universidade Nova de Lisboa, NOVAFRICA, and IZA. Email: catia.batista@novasbe.pt. ‡ Universidade Nova de Lisboa, NOVAFRICA, and BREAD. Email: pedro.vicente@novasbe.pt. § University of Michigan. Email: deanyang@umich.edu. 1 1 Introduction African farmers have a hard time saving. First, they are typically poverty-ridden smallholder farmers. Second, they are usually unbanked. Without access to formal financial products, namely those entailing some degree of commitment, they are easy prey to the pressures of their families and neighbors, and to their own temptations. Importantly, saving seems crucial to break the cycle of low investment and low agricultural productivity that is typical of many rural settings in Africa. Improved agricultural technologies, with the potential to have clear impacts on productivity, have yet to arrive in the African continent (e.g., fertilizer use is the lowest in the world). Enabling access to formal savings seems to be part of the solution to this development challenge. At the same time, the so-called mobile money revolution is making its way in the African continent. The first mobile money service, M-PESA, was launched in 2007 in Kenya and was quickly adopted by a majority of the adult population of the country.1 Other countries have followed. Based on a network of agents, standard mobile money platforms enable users to save money in their accounts and to send money to other people. All they need is a mobile phone with network coverage. Mobile money has an enormous potential to expand access to formal financial products – a lot is going to happen in the next few years. However, the way to tailor mobile money services to help farmers to save is not obvious. Indeed, it is possible that mobile money by itself de-incentivizes savings by facilitating transfers to other people. Commitment savings are yet to be introduced in many mobile money platforms, often because regulators have limited evidence about their potential impact. In this paper we report on a field experiment we designed and conducted in rural Mozambique in 2013-2015 with a sample of smallholder farmers cultivating maize in non-irrigated plots. Mobile money has recently been launched in Mozambique. We ask whether a custom-made savings account offered through mobile money, which remunerated average balances held, increases savings by farmers. We also verify whether investment in improved inputs, with an emphasis on fertilizer, and household expenditures increase as a result. Our design also enables venturing into why access to the savings account may change farmer behavior: we aimed to induce exogenous changes in social pressure to share resources within farming networks, by varying whether 1 See Jack and Suri (2011) and Mbiti and Weil (2011) for a detailed description of the introduction of MPESA in Kenya. 2 individual farmers and their closest farming friends are given similar opportunities. This exogenous variation is interacted with the introduction of the savings account. Specifically, our experimental design is a 2×2 design, based on two randomized treatments: access to the savings account through mobile money, and the symmetric treatment of the closest two farming friends of primary experimental subjects. All primary experimental subjects were given: an introduction to mobile money services, which included a free mobile phone, mobile money registration, and trials offering seed money; and an information module on urea fertilizer use, which included the opportunity to sell maize and to purchase urea fertilizer. The savings account was active before planting season until the time when urea fertilizer should be applied (at the time the maize had grown knee-high). Our measurement of outcomes is based on: (i) administrative data for mobile money transactions made available by the mobile money operator that partnered with us in our experiment, and for sales of maize and purchases of fertilizer; (ii) survey data related to savings; (iii) survey data for fertilizer use; (iv) survey data for household expenditures; and (v) survey data for transfers sent and received. Since we conducted both baseline and follow-up surveys, we are able to estimate difference-in-difference regressions with individual fixed effects for some of the outcome variables. We find clear positive effects of the savings account treatment on savings in the mobile money platform, especially during the first year, when the account was active. We also observe a positive impact of the savings treatment on the total and average values of mobile money transactions. The role of transfers received in the mobile money system seems to be particularly important in mediating these effects. Overall household savings seem to increase as well. On agricultural inputs, we report that the probability of using fertilizer increased by 31-36 percentage points at the 1 percent level of statistical significance, when considering farmers approached individually by experimenters. The use of other improved inputs also increased as a result. Importantly, we see that household expenditures increased, in particular non-frequent ones, which is indicative of welfare improvements. We have evidence that the likelihood that individuals lent/borrowed money to/from their connections decreased with the savings treatment. The second dimension of our experimental variation, on symmetric treatment of closest farming friends, enables us to propose that network social pressure to share resources is a possible force working against savings. We find some evidence, though not always statistically significant, that the symmetric 3 treatment increased the general use of mobile money, and reduced household expenditures and lending to social networks. These patterns are consistent with lower social pressure induced by the symmetric (network) treatment. Significant interaction effects between the two treatments hint that the savings account enabled counteracting social pressure with regards savings. This paper contributes to the literatures on risk sharing within social networks in rural settings, commitment savings, input investment by smallholder farmers, and mobile money. Seminal work by Townsend (1994) and Udry (1994) documented the importance of informal risk sharing in rural settings for insuring against idiosyncratic risk. Indeed, social pressure to share resources within networks is a powerful force at work in many developing countries.2 In order to counteract these pressures but also to limit individual time-inconsistency problems, access to savings accounts with various degrees of commitment has been documented to increase savings and investment in different settings (e.g., Ashraf et al., 2006, Dupas and Robinson, 2013). Consistently, Duflo et al. (2011) have shown that small discounts for fertilizer purchase just after harvest time could significantly increase agricultural investment in fertilizer.3 Specifically for Mozambique, in a similar setting to ours, recent contributions have tested the impact of input subsidies and saving incentives (Carter et al., 2013, 2014, 2016). These authors find that a matched savings program can be particularly effective at raising farmer consumption while controlling risk. The recent mobile money literature has focused on M-PESA and its risk sharing consequences. Jack et al. (2012) and Jack and Suri (2013) show that the consumption of households with access to M-PESA does not suffer from idiosyncratic shocks, which implies that decreased transaction costs for transfers drive more risk sharing. Our paper tests the impact of a very different mechanism of change for the introduction of mobile money, in line with the commitment savings literature. The recent paper by Jack and Suri (2016) also documents positive effects of mobile money on savings, along with impacts on occupational choices of women. The paper is organized as follows. In section 2 we present the context of our field experiment. In section 3 we fully develop the experimental design, with treatments, hypotheses, sampling and assignment to treatment, measurement, and estimation strategy. The following section provides the econometric results, including balance tests, treatment effects on use of mobile money, 2 A study of credit cooperatives in Cameroon by Baland et al. (2011) shows members bearing significant costs to protect their savings from friends and relatives. 3 Duflo et al. (2008) show that, in the same setting of their other study, fertilizer use in specific quantities has a clear impact on farmer welfare through increased productivity. 4 savings, agricultural inputs use, expenditures, and transfers from/to closest farming friends. We conclude in section 5. 2 Context Mozambique, a country with 25.8 million inhabitants, is one of the poorest countries in the world with GDP per capita of 1105 USD (current, PPP) in 2013 - it ranks 175 in 181 countries in terms of GDP per capita. Despite substantial natural resource discoveries and exploration in recent years, it is still a country with clear dependence on official aid assistance, which accounts for 57 percent of central government expenses. Agriculture is considered the key sector in Mozambique for those interested in pro-poor economic policies. This is because it accounts for 81 percent of employment in the country. Despite this impressive figure, the contribution of the agricultural sector for the value added of the country is only 29 percent.4 Cereal agricultural productivity for 2011 in Mozambique was 10.4 thousand hectograms per hectare, well below the world average, 36.6, and even below the African average, 14.4.5 Two factors may help explaining this low agricultural productivity. First, smallholder farmers constitute the vast majority of farmers in the country: data from the National Agricultural Survey (TIA) in 2008 indicate that only 0.58 percent of Mozambican farmers cultivate more than 10 hectares of land. Second, investment in improved inputs is very limited: e.g., FAO Statistical Yearbook reports that in 2011 the Mozambican average for nitrogen fertilizer use was 6.4 kilograms per hectare, which is well below both the world average (73.3) and the African average (13.3). In an extremely poor setting like rural Mozambique, it is likely that smallholder farmers have difficulties in saving resources, from harvest to planting, for investing in improved agricultural inputs like fertilizers.6 Access to financial services is very limited in Mozambique, specifically in rural areas. In 2013, only 24 bank accounts existed for each 100 Mozambican adults, and the number of bank branches per 100,000 adults was 3.9. Both figures were below their corresponding African averages, which 4 World Development Indicators, 2015, latest available years. FAO Statistical Yearbook, 2014. 6 Cunguara and Darnhofer (2011) show that improved agricultural technologies are associated with higher household incomes for smallholder farmers in Mozambique when these farmers have secured access to markets. 5 5 were 55 and 7.7, respectively.7 Saving methods for the rural population are often limited to keeping money at home, keeping money informally with someone, and to participating in savings groups.8 The introduction of mobile money in 2011 created expectations that the level of financial inclusion could improve quickly in the country. Mozambique had around five million subscribers of mobile phone services in a competitive market, and geographical coverage included 80 percent of the population.9 mKesh became the first mobile money service operating in Mozambique: it is offered by Carteira Móvel, a financial institution created by Mcel, the main mobile telecommunication operator in the country. During the first years most of mKesh’s expansion efforts, specifically in terms of agent coverage, were concentrated in urban locations.10 Even though the Mozambican Central Bank does not allow mobile money operators to offer saving products of their own (i.e., earning interest), mobile money can still be seen as an attractive saving method, namely for farmers who live far from bank branches. 3 Experimental design 3.1 Treatments Our experiment encompasses two treatments, interacted in a 2×2 design, submitted at the individual level. The pool of primary experimental subjects includes 196 farmers at the baseline. All primary experimental subjects were given two information modules after the baseline, one on mobile money and one on the use of fertilizer. The first treatment is a savings treatment, which allows individuals to receive a bonus (or interest) depending on average balances they have on their mobile money account. The second treatment is a network treatment, by which farmers had their two closest farming friends given the information modules on mobile money and fertilizer use. The interaction of the savings and network treatments provides farmers’ connections with access to the bonus as well. 7 IMF, Financial Access Survey, 2015. Batista and Vicente (2012) report for a large sample of rural households surveyed in 2012 the following statistics: 63 percent save money at home, 30 percent save money informally with someone, and 21 percent participate in a savings group. Only 21 percent report any money saved in a bank account. 9 Computed from data made available by Mcel and Vodacom, the two existing Mozambican mobile telecommunication operators in 2011. In 2012 a third operator entered the mobile phone market (Movitel). 10 M-Pesa, operated through a financial institution controlled by Vodacom, entered the mobile money market in late 2013, after our experiment had started. 8 6 The information module was a general introduction to mKesh, the only mobile money service being offered in Mozambique at the time of the experiment. The module started by offering a simple mobile phone (worth 750 Meticais, close to USD 30 in an Mcel shop) and a leaflet explaining how to use mKesh (giving an overview of all possible services on offer). See Figure 1 for a depiction of this leaflet. Verbally, enumerators stressed what saving means, what a bank is, and some details of mKesh (ability to save there, safety based on a PIN, no need to go to the bank). After this verbal introduction, enumerators registered each individual on mKesh using the self-registration feature of the service, and gave 55 Meticais (close to USD 2) for cash-in (deposit) in mKesh. In the process of the cash-in operation, enumerators introduced the local mKesh agents to the experimental subjects. After the cash-in operation, enumerators helped each individual to check his/her mKesh balance. Enumerators also explained how to cash-out (withdraw) the money from mKesh (making sure individuals understood that they had to pay a commission of 5 Meticais for that operation). <Figure 1 near here> The module on fertilizer use was based on a leaflet (see Figure 2), which was delivered by enumerators and explained verbally. It focused on maize production and its main message was ‘Using fertilizer is good! This year take good care of your machamba [plot]. Increase your production by increasing your soil fertility’. Details of fertilizer use were explained on one of the sides of the leaflet: they included information on what farmers already do well (prepare the soil, place seeds after first rains, use of organic fertilizer, remove unwanted plants from plot during maize growth), and added information on how to apply urea as inorganic fertilizer two to three weeks after germination. These details were verbally discussed at length with experimental subjects. At the end of the module on fertilizer use, farmers were given information on the possibility of selling their maize to a local buyer (Desenvolvimento e Comercialização Agrícola DECA). Note that the survey team was available to mediate these sales, i.e., for the maize that farmers had to sell from the previous season (harvested in July). mKesh was one of the payment methods made available to farmers. The survey team was also available to mediate the sale of fertilizer, for the growing season starting in November 2013. These were resources available during visits performed until planting season. <Figure 2 near here> 7 The savings treatment was based on the offer of a bonus of 20% interest for the average mKesh balance held by an individual over the period from the end of the survey team visits before planting season to the follow-up survey in January/February 2014 (just after when urea fertilizer should be applied). This bonus was paid in urea fertilizer. The leaflet that was distributed announcing this treatment scheme is depicted in Figure 3. Note that, even though experimental subjects could cash-out the money on their mobile money account, they faced a strong incentive to maintain a high balance for as much time as possible until the follow-up survey. Interest rates paid by banks in Mozambique approached but did not reach 10% on a full year in 2013 (as given by the reference rate of the Bank of Mozambique). Hence the savings treatment can be seen as a commitment-savings intervention. <Figure 3 near here> The network treatment gave the two closest farming friends of each treated primary experimental subject the modules on mobile money and fertilizer use. In addition to these modules, when interacted with the savings treatment, the network treatment also enabled access of closest friends to the bonus for average mKesh balances. Closest farming friends were defined through questions on identifying a primary experimental subject’s (i) closest friends in the same community that farm non-irrigated plots, (ii) connections in the same community that farm non-irrigated plots from whom that individual had a loan granted, and (iii) connections in the same community that farm non-irrigated plots to whom that individual granted a loan. In addition, the selected closest friends had to have a mobile phone number (as indicated by the primary experimental subject) and could not be in the list of primary experimental subjects. When more than two farming friends were mentioned across the referred questions, priority was given to connections that were mentioned in more than one of the (i) to (iii) lists for a given individual. 3.2 Hypotheses The experimental design that is offered by our structure of treatments is depicted in Figure 4. The group that is not exposed to either the savings or network treatments is labeled CI (for control, i.e., no savings treatment, and for individual, i.e., no network treatment). The group that is exposed to the savings treatment but not to the network treatment is labeled SI. The group that is not exposed to the savings treatment but is exposed to the network treatment is labeled CN. 8 Finally, the group facing the interaction between the two treatments is labeled SN. We denote below (!) as our outcome variables of interest. <Figure 4 near here> Our first hypothesis is that the savings treatment adoption of mobile money services, savings in particular, and investment on improved inputs, with a potential impact on household expenditures. This is because experimental subjects face, with the savings treatment, a clear incentive to save and, therefore, to invest in their farming businesses, with possible improvements in household welfare. Note that all primary experimental subjects are subject to the modules on mKesh and on fertilizer use, which guarantee that they are familiar with the specific savings treatment proposed and with the benefits of fertilizer. Hence, taking the group of experimental subjects that is treated individually, we expect SI to have higher levels of the referred outcomes than CI, i.e., !(!") − !(!") > 0. Hypothesis 1a: The savings treatment increases adoption of mobile money services, savings in particular, investment on agricultural inputs, and household expenditures, when taking the group of experimental subjects that is approached individually, i.e., !(!") − !(!") > 0. Applying a similar rationale, we expect that the savings intervention increases the level of the referred outcomes for the group of experimental subjects that is treated together with closest connections. Consistently, we anticipate TN to have higher levels of the outcomes than CN, i.e., !(!") − !(!") > 0. However, if social pressure from closest farming friends is minimal when the full network is treated, and the motive for adoption of the mKesh possibilities is protection from one’s network, this difference could be zero, i.e., ! !" − ! !" = 0. Hypothesis 1b: The savings treatment weakly increases the level of our outcomes of interest, when taking the group that is approached together with closest connections, i.e., !(!") − !(!") ≥ 0. It is possible that faced with the network treatment alone our experimental subjects are more likely to adopt mobile money services. We propose two possible motives. The first is that subjects treated individually face more social pressure from their connections to lend them money, as primary individuals were given a set of opportunities (the mKesh information and 9 fertilizer modules) that was not available to their connections. This is what we call the social pressure explanation. The second is that primary individuals feel more confident about mKesh services since they know other people around them know about mobile money and are likely users as well. This is what we call the network imitation/information explanation.11 For the group of individuals that was not given the savings treatment, this corresponds to !(!!) − !(!") > 0. Hypothesis 2a: The network treatment increases adoption of mobile money services, when taking the group of experimental subjects that is not given the savings treatment, i.e., !(!") − !(!") > 0. If one takes the first motive described above (social pressure), then it is unclear whether we should observe the same difference as for Hypothesis 2a when taking the group of experimental subjects that was given the savings treatment. This is because the savings treatment gives primary subjects access to commitment savings, which could act as a shield against social pressure to share resources. However, the second motive would simply yield the same difference as before, i.e., !(!") − !(!") > 0. Hypothesis 2b: The network treatment weakly increases adoption of mobile money services when taking the group that is given the savings treatment, i.e., ! !" − ! !" ≥ 0.12 In our experimental design, we are also able to test what happens to our outcomes of interest when individuals are exposed to the savings treatment and to the network treatment at the same time. The social pressure explanation would yield ! !" − ! !" − ! !" − ! !" < 0. Otherwise, the sign of this double difference would be unclear.13 11 Conley and Udry (2010) show the importance of social networks in learning about and adopting new agricultural technologies. Note that a positive effect of the network treatment could also be due to an increased perception of the value of the network in face of the introduction of mobile money. It is however unlikely that there is an increased network externality at the level of closest (locally) farming friends. 12 Note that for both Hypothesis 2a and Hypothesis 2b we could also consider the possibility that negative differences are observed. The motive could be that subjects treated together with their networks would freeride on each other in terms of savings, since they are aware the others were given the same set of new opportunities. 13 Note that imitation and information would in principle yield positive interaction effects. However, if information is not assumed additive, i.e., people either learn alone about mKesh or through their network but not in both ways, it could yield a negative interaction effect. 10 Hypothesis 3: The savings and network treatment interaction decreases the adoption of mobile money services when the savings treatment is taken as a shield against social pressure to share resources, i.e., ! !" − ! !" − ! !" − ! !" < 0. Otherwise, the sign of the interaction is unclear. 3.3 Sampling and assignment to treatment This project was implemented in the districts of Manica, Mossurize, and Sussundenga, in the Mozambican province of Manica. In each district, a set of localities, 15 in total, was identified namely as having farmer associations. We asked for lists of farmers in each of the localities and surveyed these farmers in a pre-project survey. 240 farmers operating non-irrigated plots who also provided information about their connections were surveyed at that point in June-July 2013. Within these, we were able to identify a set of 196 farmers in the same 15 localities with two connections each (both willing to participate in the study). These 196 farmers were interviewed during our baseline survey, which took place in July-August 2013, and form our list of primary experimental subjects. Each triplet at the baseline (defined as one primary experimental subject and his/her two connections) was assigned to one of the four comparison groups (control, savings treatment, network treatment, and interaction between savings and network treatments). The procedure was the following. We first composed blocks of four triplets within the same locality and using observable characteristics of primary farmers collected in the pre-project survey (type of secondary occupation, whether he/she operated irrigated plots, whether he/she had used fertilizer). We then randomly assigned each member of each block to a different comparison group. The post-intervention survey was implemented in January-February 2014, after the planting season was over, and after the urea fertilizer could be applied in that season. Of the 196 primary farmers, we were able to survey 186 individuals, which entails an attrition rate of 5%. We check below balance in observable characteristics for both baseline and post-intervention samples. 3.4 Measurement 11 Our measurement can be divided in three different types of data: (i) administrative data from mKesh; (ii) survey data from pre-project, baseline, and post-intervention surveys; and (iii) sale records of maize and purchase records of urea fertilizer mediated by enumerators. The administrative data from mKesh includes balance and transaction data for all experimental subjects for the relevant period of study, starting with the end of the survey team visits before planting season in 2013 to the end of June 2015, for approximately two years. Sale records of maize regard sales of maize through enumerators under the arrangement with DECA after the baseline survey, and purchase records of fertilizer regard purchases of urea fertilizer through enumerators during the planting season in November-December 2013. Enumerators recorded all details of these transactions. Finally, the survey data we employ ahead, which focus on baseline and post-intervention survey data, include information on respondent and household characteristics, mobile phone use and mKesh literacy, agricultural practices, financial literacy and practices (including savings), household expenses and assets, relationship with the two connected farmers, information on transfers sent/received. 3.5 Estimation strategy Our empirical approach is based on estimating treatment effects on the variety of outcome variables that we have available. We now describe the main econometric specifications we employ for the estimation of these parameters. Our design allows us to estimate average treatment effects in different ways. Most simply, the effect of interest (!) could be estimated through the specification: !!,!,!"#$ = ! + !!!,! + !!,!,!"#$ , (1) where ! is an outcome of interest, !, !, 1!are identifiers for locations, individuals, and time specifically, 1!represents the follow-up measurement -, ! = !!! effects of interest, and !!,! = [!!!,! !!,! !! !!" ! is the vector of !!,! ×!!,! !]′ is a vector of dummy variables representing the treatments (savings, !, and network, !) and their interaction. 12 Looking at the working hypotheses presented above, we can easily relate the hypothesized differences between comparison groups, under the social pressure mechanism, with the coefficients of interest in our specification, as follows: H1a: ! !" − ! !" > 0 ⇔ !! > 0 H1b: ! !" − ! !" = 0 ⇔ !! +!!" = 0 H2a: ! !" − ! !" > 0 ⇔ !! > 0 H2b: ! !" − ! !" = 0 ⇔ !! +!!" = 0 H3: ! !" − ! !" − ! !" − ! !" < 0 ⇔ !!" < 0 In this setting, because of limited sample size, we add controls to compose our main specification: although controls do not generally change the estimate for the average treatment effect, they can help explaining the dependent variable, and therefore typically lower the standard error of the coefficient of interest. We then have the following core specification: !!,!,!"#$ = ! + !!!,! + !!!,! + !!,!,!"#$ , (2) where !!,! is a vector of location and individual (demographic) controls. We also employ a difference-in-differences specification, where baseline data are included, assuming parallel trends in the different comparison groups. We use specifications with location and individual controls, or with individual fixed effects, which control for time-invariant unobservable individual characteristics. The latter is displayed here: !!,!,! = !! + !! + !! + !"!,! ×! + !!,!,! , (3) where !! is an individual fixed effect and ! is a time (before-after) dummy variable. For ease of interpretation and transparency, we employ OLS estimations throughout the paper. Given our randomization procedure at the individual level, we estimate robust standard errors in all regressions. 13 4 Econometric results 4.1 Balance We begin by showing balance tests for the primary farmers in the comparison groups of our experiment. These are displayed in Tables 1. We present average values for a wide range of observable individual characteristics of the control group (CI), and differences of this group to the other three groups. We test the statistical significance of these differences. We also test the overall significance of all differences by employing a joint F-test, for which we report p-values. Note that in the first columns of the tables, we focus on the full baseline sample of primary farmers. Because we have some attrition regarding this sample in the follow-up survey (186 out of 196 individuals were surveyed at that point), we focus on the follow-up sample in the second set of columns in the tables. This allows seeing whether unbalances between the comparison groups were associated with the panel attrition. <Tables 1 near here> From the 37 individual characteristics that we tested, we can observe unbalances for age, number of children, number of plots, and whether the farmer used improved seeds. These differences to the control group concern the network or the interaction groups. They are significant at the 10 percent level, except for the number of children, which is significant at the 5 percent level. The Fstat on the null hypothesis of joint no differences is only rejected for the numbers of household members and children. When we look at the follow-up sample, we face similar results: gender becomes significant for both the savings and network differences to the control group, and whether the farmer saves at home becomes significant for the network difference to the control group, but several statistically significant differences in the baseline disappear, namely for age, number of plots, and whether the farmer used improved seeds. Overall, we can conclude that we do not seem to identify differences across comparison groups beyond what is statistically acceptable (in the baseline only 4 out of 111 differences tested are found to be statistically significant). In any event, we will employ basic demographic controls in our regressions, namely variables for which we found statistically significant differences across comparison groups. An additional note goes to the characterization of our sample of primary farmers. We can observe in Tables 1 that the control group is mainly male (90 percent), average age is 43 years, most 14 farmers were born in Manica province (92 percent), the average number of household members is 6.9, and the average number of children is 4.3. As farmers, this group, on average, has been cultivating a plot for 10 years, has 2 different plots, and their main plots have 4.3 hectares; in the last year before the experiment, 22 percent used improved seeds for maize, 16 percent used fertilizer for maize, and 76 percent of the maize produced was sold. On finance, 26 percent report having a bank account, for 7 years on average; 82 percent save at home, and 14 percent contribute to a saving group. Finally, 25 percent of these households have an improved latrine, 28 percent have access to electricity, and 50 percent have access to piped water or a protected spring. 4.2 Administrative data: mKesh use, maize and fertilizer sales We now turn to our analysis of treatment effects. We begin by showing results related to the use of mKesh by exploring administrative data per transaction made available by the mKesh operator. These are displayed in Tables 2. These data concern the period from the last visit of the survey team before planting season in 2013 to the end of June 2015, for the total of approximately two years. We focus our attention on the following outcome variables: log average daily savings in mKesh (separating between the first and the second years of data), log total value of transactions in mKesh, and the log average value of transactions in mKesh. We also look at different types of mKesh transactions in value by using squared-roots of total value transacted (not to drop zeros), specifically cash-ins, top-ups of airtime, transfers received, transfers sent, payments, and cashouts. Note that experimentation transactions made as part of the module on the introduction to mKesh are not taken into account in our analysis except for savings (since experimental subjects were faced with a decision on savings regarding trial money). For each outcome, we display two one-difference specifications for the sample of primary farmers, since there is no baseline mKesh data in our design, the first employing district dummies only, and the second adding individual controls (like in specification 2 above).14 We test all five hypotheses proposed above: H1a, H2a, and H3 correspond to individual significance tests of the three main regression coefficients; H1b and H2b correspond to tests of linear hypotheses displayed at the bottom panel of the table. We also add the test of joint significance of all three main regressors. <Tables 2 near here> 14 Individual controls are basic demographic variables: gender, age, whether the individual was born in Manica province, whether the individual has completed primary school, number of household members, and number of children. 15 We observe that the savings treatment increased average daily savings in mKesh in the first year of the experiment, when the experimental savings account was active. This is specifically for the sample of primary experimental farmers that did not receive the network treatment. The magnitude of this effect was 38-44 percent, statistically significant at the 5 or 10 percent levels. Note that the point estimate in the second year is still positive and sizeable, even though statistical significance is not achieved. We also report positive treatment effects of the savings treatment for individually approached farmers when considering the total value of transactions and the average value of transactions in mKesh. The magnitudes are 78-84 percent (total value) and 69 percent (average value), statistically significant at the 10 percent value. These findings indicate that the savings treatment was effective at increasing mKesh adoption for the group not given the network treatment, in particular for savings. We can then conclude that H1a is confirmed but not a strictly positively signed H1b, in line with our social pressure explanation. When looking at the different types of transactions, we note that the savings treatment only produced significant positive effects for the value of transfers received, for both the group not given the network treatment and the group given that treatment. These effects are significant at the 1 or 5 percent levels. We also observe that the network treatment, only when considering the sample of individuals that was not subject to the savings treatment, seems to increase the total and average values of mKesh transactions, even though these effects are not statistically significant. These results are suggestive of H2a, which is consistent with the idea that when faced with the network intervention alone, subjects feel less social pressure from their connections to share resources, and use more mKesh. Finally, we observe that the interaction coefficient is robustly negative for average daily savings, total value of transactions, and average value of transactions, even if statistical significance is not achieved (borderline for total value of transactions). These effects are suggestive that H3 is supported, namely that when the savings treatments is applied together with the network treatment, there is less of a social pressure motive for mKesh use and savings, and both decrease.15 We now report on the maize sales and fertilizer purchases by our primary experimental subjects, which were mediated by our survey team. Our data are based on the actual records of these 15 The alternative explanation for a negative interaction effect, related to information that is not additive, seems not be verified as we do not find statistically significant network or interaction effects when employing variables related to information about mKesh (specifically behavioral variables built from observing whether subjects were able to check mKesh balances and from asking whether they wanted to withdraw trial mKesh money). These results are available upon request. 16 sales/purchases. From the baseline survey to the planting season, all experimental subjects had the option to sell maize through our survey team to a local buyer. mKesh was available as a payment method for these sales. The possibility of purchase of urea fertilizer was also made available before planting by the survey team to all experimental subjects. We consider three outcome variables in Table 3: whether maize was sold through the survey team, the percentage of maize value that was sold through the survey team using mKesh, and whether fertilizer was purchased through the survey team. The specifications are the same as the ones displayed in Tables 2. <Table 3 near here> We find that the network treatment increases the likelihood that maize was sold through the survey team, by 14-15 percentage points (significant at the 5 percent level). This is possibly due to a network imitation/information explanation, by which networked individuals influence each other towards selling maize through the survey team. The social pressure explanation is also consistent with this result as individuals treated jointly with their networks of closest farming friends may have felt lower incentive to hide their maize sales from potential pressures to share resources. We should note, consistently with the social pressure explanation, that this effect is only significant for subjects not facing the savings treatment. We also observe that among those selling maize through the survey team, there is a clear impact of the savings treatment on the likelihood of selling maize through the survey team using mKesh. This is a positive effect of 7792 percentage points for the sample of individuals not facing the network treatment, significant at the 1 percent level. For the sample facing the network treatment, effects vary between 0.7 and 0.83, with the same level of statistical significance. These effects of the savings treatment, which are in accordance with the effects reported on transfers received in the administrative data from the mobile money operator, reinforce the idea that this treatment induced the use of mKesh for saving purposes. Finally, we do not find statistical significant effects on the likelihood of buying fertilizer through the survey team, even though we can report positive point estimates for the savings treatment alone. 4.3 Survey-based measures of savings We now turn to survey outcomes. In Tables 4 we show our treatment effects for information outcomes related to the definition of savings, extensive margin of different types of savings, 17 specifically saving at home, saving in a bank account, saving with a shopkeeper, saving in gold and saving in animals, and intensive margin of savings (in log value at the time of surveying), namely at home, in a bank account, and aggregate over all survey-measured types of savings. Hence, we are covering here the main alternatives to saving in mKesh as depicted in Table 2a. We expect that the savings treatment effect is not as clearly positive as it is for mKesh savings: in fact it could be negative if there is substitution between savings in mKesh and other types of savings. We are also agnostic with respect to the effect of the network treatment: if one takes social pressure as the main driving force behind this treatment, it could be positive due to lower social pressure to share resources; however, it could also be negative if this treatment nudges individuals to move (or to report moving) their savings out of standard (non-mKesh) savings. Since we have available baseline data for saving methods beyond mKesh measured through both their extensive and intensive margins, we display difference-in-difference specifications including both district dummies and full individual controls, or including individual fixed effects (as in specification 3 above). Note that difference-in-difference specifications may be most reliable for saving at home, given the statistically significant difference between two comparison groups for this variable at the baseline (shown in Table 1b). <Tables 4 near here> We begin by observing positive effects of the savings treatment (in the sample not targeted by the network treatment) on the information variables related to the definition of savings, namely on whether subjects mentioned plan and wise spending and referred friends’ help when asked about the definition of savings. The magnitude of these effects is 10-11 (plan and wise spending) and 67 (friends’ help) percentage points, statistically significant at the 5 or 10 percent levels. We also note positive and significant effects of the network treatment (for the sample not targeted by the savings treatment) for the variable related to planning and wise spending, and negative and significant interaction effects for the variable related to friends’ help. Both are consistent with the social pressure explanation proposed in this paper. Turning to non-mKesh types of saving, we find a range of different results. Looking at the extensive margin results, while we see some positive and significant point estimates of the effect of the savings treatment, namely for saving in animals (sample with network treatment), we find some negative and significant point estimates as well, namely for saving at home (sample with network treatment) and saving with shopkeeper (sample with no network treatment). These 18 findings indicate that the savings treatment may incentivize other types of savings beyond mKesh, but may also lead to substituting away from some standard methods of saving. Looking at the intensive margin results, we see positive effects of the savings treatment on the aggregate value of savings as reported in the surveys by aggregating non-mKesh methods of saving. This is statistically significant at the 1 or 5 percent levels when considering the sample of primary experimental subjects that were given the network treatment: the magnitude of this effect is 131181 percent. We also identify mostly negative and significant effects of the network treatment, consistently with the idea that experimental subjects could be moving or reporting to move their savings out of some standard saving methods nudged by the symmetric network intervention (possibly as free-riding on their treated networks in terms of savings). We can conclude that, while we see positive effects on the non-mKesh aggregate value of savings, we see a mixed pattern of treatment effects on specific methods of saving. 4.4 Agricultural inputs We now report the treatment effects related to the use of agricultural inputs for the primary experimental farmers. Table 5 shows effects on synthetic fertilizer use in the previous season, both in terms of extensive and of intensive (kilograms) margins. Note that urea was the fertilizer type that was central to the module on fertilizer use that was submitted to experimental subjects. In this context, the survey team mediated purchases of urea. It distributed saving bonuses in urea as well. We expect that the treatment centered on mKesh savings produces a clear positive effect on the take-up of fertilizer. Table 5 also shows treatment effects on knowledge about using urea fertilizer (assessed through an index of four equally weighted binary variables constructed from four different survey questions: one asking about the appropriate distance to the plant for the application of fertilizer, one asking about the appropriate depth for the application of fertilizer, one asking about the appropriate quantity of fertilizer per plant, and one asking about the appropriate timing for the application of fertilizer), on the number of workers in the subject’s farm, on owning irrigation pumps, on employing improved seeds, and on using organic fertilizer (all questions about the use of inputs referred to the previous season). We show one-difference or difference-in-difference specifications depending on the outcome variable, following the models presented in the previous tables. Baseline data are available and so difference-in-difference specifications are possible for fertilizer use (intensive margin), and owning irrigation pumps. For the remaining outcomes we employ one-difference specifications. 19 <Table 5 near here> We find that the likelihood that fertilizer was used clearly increased with the savings treatment. This effect ranges between 31 and 36 percentage points, when considering the sample not facing the network intervention, and between 40 and 41 percentage points, when considering the sample facing the network treatment. It is significant at the 1 percent level for all specifications employed. This is clear evidence indicating that the savings treatment was particularly effective at increasing fertilizer use. We do not find, however, statistically significant effects on the intensive margin of fertilizer use, despite positive point estimates. Note that the average report of urea fertilizer acquired was 47.3Kgs, while the average quantity of urea fertilizer given in bonuses for the savings treatment was 0.9Kgs, and the average quantity of urea fertilizer bought from the survey team was 2.8Kgs. We also note that in the group of farmers that received a bonus in fertilizer, i.e., through the savings treatment, only 51 percent reported having used fertilizer. This evidence shows that the impact of the savings treatment on fertilizer use is unlikely to have been driven by the specific quantities of fertilizer distributed as bonuses, or even by fertilizer sold through the survey team. Our outcome variable related to knowledge about using urea fertilizer reinforces this picture: we find a positive effect of the savings treatment on the likelihood of knowing about how to use urea fertilizer (for the sample not given the network treatment) ranging between 15 and 18 percentage points, significant at the 5 or 10 percent levels. We do not find clear patterns of network or interaction effects on use/knowledge of fertilizer. Looking at other agricultural inputs, we find positive effects of the savings treatment for the sample of subjects not given the network treatment for number of workers in farm, owning irrigation pumps, using improved seeds, and using organic fertilizer. However, these are only statistically significant for irrigation pumps: the probability of owning theses inputs increases by 7 percentage points, significant at the 10 percent level (relative to just 1 percent of CI farmers owning these pumps). Note that the probability of using improved seeds also increases significantly with the savings treatment when considering the sample of farmers given the network treatment: this is a 17 percentage-point increase in the specification without individual controls. We can conclude that we have some evidence that the savings treatment was able to cause positive changes in agricultural investment beyond the use of fertilizer. 4.5 Household expenditure 20 We present in Table 6 treatment effects for different types of household expenditure, specifically day-to-day and non-frequent expenditures, as well as total expenditures. These data were collected in both surveys conducted during this experiment. We expect that the intervention offering the savings account in mKesh increases the level of non-frequent expenditures more clearly than the level of day-to-day expenditures. This is because it is more likely savings are used for buying non-frequent goods and services. It is possible that the network intervention decreases expenditures due to diminished social pressure. We present difference-in-difference specifications in line with the previous tables. <Table 6 near here> Results in Table 6 show that the savings treatment increased non-frequent expenditures by 56 percent when considering the sample that was not given the network treatment, and by 83-88 percent when considering the sample that was given the network treatment. These are statistically significant effects at the 5 or 10 percent levels. Day-to-day expenditures yield insignificant effects for the savings treatment. Overall, this is evidence that the savings treatment was more effective at increasing non-frequent purchases of goods and services. Interestingly, we find robust effects of the savings treatment on total expenditures, which is suggestive of a positive welfare effect. The magnitude of these effects ranges between 58 and 64 percent for the sample without the network treatment (significant at the 5 or 10 percent levels), and between 61 and 62 percent for the sample with the network treatment (significant at the 5 percent level). The network treatment had an overall negative effect for all types of expenditures, when taking into account the sample of individuals not given access to the savings account in mKesh. However, this effect is never statistically significant. This finding is suggestive that lower social pressure to share resources within social networks induced lower expenses. Overall, we find evidence that the savings treatment induced higher aggregate household expenditures, driven by non-frequent ones. 4.6 Transfers sent and received Finally, we analyze treatment effects for whether primary farmers lent to their closest farming friends, and for whether they borrowed from their closest farming friends. We also report the treatment effects on the log amounts of transfers sent and received, as well as on whether lending/borrowing to/from closest friends were for current consumption. These results are displayed in Table 7. This information was collected at the time of the follow-up survey. We 21 expect the savings treatment to decrease lending and the sending of transfers in particular, as treated individuals gain an attractive option for their savings. We also expect the network treatment to decrease lending, as social pressure to share resources decreases. However, the same effects could be expected for borrowing and receiving transfers as well, if consumption/savings become less/more important. We show regressions employing district dummies only, and regressions employing district dummies and individual controls. <Table 7 near here> As expected, we observe that the savings treatment decreases all outcomes related to lending/borrowing in Table 7, when considering the sample of primary experimental subjects that was not subject to the network treatment. We see a statistically significant effect for borrowing from closest farming friends: this is a 10 percentage-point effect, significant at the 10 percent level. We also find a positive and significant effect on borrowing for current consumption purposes, when considering only the individuals that borrowed from closest farming friends.16 When considering the sample that was given the network intervention, we actually observe some significant positive effects for lending/borrowing, driven by the interaction coefficient. A possible explanation is that individuals that are given access to the mKesh savings account jointly with their networks are nudged to pool more resources. Also as expected, we report consistently negative effects of the network treatment in the sample of experimental subjects that was not given the savings intervention. These are statistically significant for log amount of transfers sent and for borrowing from closest farming friends for consumption purposes. Note that when we consider the sample of individuals that was faced with the savings intervention, again driven by the interaction coefficient, we identify positive and significant effects for borrowing. The interaction coefficient is clearly positive for both lending and borrowing. For lending it reaches 16 percentage points, significant at the 10 percent level, and for borrowing it ranges between 25 and 29 percentage points, significant at the 1 percent level. We also see positive and significant interaction effects on borrowing for consumption purposes. In face of the social pressure explanation of our results, this is the expected sign, as the mKesh savings account decreases lending/borrowing but less so when networks are less demanding. 16 In face of the savings treatment, for farmers not exposed to the network treatment, it could be the case that primary farmers would share access to the new savings account with their closest friends. Our findings on borrowing from closest farming friends suggest that possibility did not happen. 22 5 Concluding remarks In this paper, we analyzed the results of a field experiment where a savings account operated through a mobile money platform was introduced to smallholder farmers in rural Mozambique. We find that access to the savings account increased the amount of money saved in mobile money, total transactions in that platform, and aggregate household savings. Investment in agricultural inputs increased as result. We are also able to identify a positive effect on total household expenditures, which is suggestive of a welfare impact. The experiment also varied whether closest farming friends were given access to the same opportunities offered to primary experimental subjects. Beyond the savings account, these opportunities included being introduced to mobile money and given information about fertilizer use. We interpret asymmetry within networks as increased social pressure to share resources. Our results are consistent with this hypothesis. We have suggestive evidence that the symmetric network treatment increased the use of mKesh and decreased lending/borrowing to/from closest friends. Overall, our evidence hints that the savings account could be used to counteract social pressure. This research shows that mobile money can be used effectively to increase financial inclusion in a country like Mozambique. Farmers are particularly in need of financial products that enable them to save resources from harvest to planting, namely to invest in improved inputs like fertilizer. Access to a tailored savings account can lead to higher levels of investment by farmers. Our study suggests that this savings account may constitute an instrument to protect savers from the pressure their social networks can exert to share resources. Since many central banks in developing countries see mobile money as a risky innovation, in need of tight regulation, many of the possibilities of mobile money are still not allowed. Our evidence suggests that enabling saving accounts to be offered through mobile money platforms is likely to be a pro-poor policy, bringing improvements for important populations. A final note on ways forward for the research in this paper: while we have found suggestive evidence in support social network pressure as a central impediment for savings, our structure of treatments, which was limited by statistical power, can be refined further, namely in terms of producing variation that can be interpreted robustly as social network pressure. 23 References Ashraf, Nava, Dean Karlan, and Wesley Yin (2006), Tying Odysseus to the Mast: Evidence from a Commitment Savings Product in the Philippines, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(2), pp. 635-672; Baland, Jean-Marie, Catherine Guirkinger, and Charlotte Mali (2011), Pretending to Be Poor: Borrowing to Escape Forced Solidarity in Cameroon, Economic Development and Cultural Change, 60(1), pp. 1-16; Batista, Cátia, and Pedro C. Vicente (2012), Introducing Mobile Money in Rural Mozambique: Evidence from a Field Experiment, Universidade Nova de Lisboa, Working Paper; Carter, Michael R., Rachid Laajaj, and Dean Yang (2013), The Impact of Voucher Coupons on the Uptake of Fertilizer and Improved Seeds: Evidence from a Randomized Trial in Mozambique, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 95(5), pp. 1345-1351; Carter, Michael R., Rachid Laajaj, and Dean Yang (2014), Subsidies and the Persistence of Technology Adoption: Field Experimental Evidence from Mozambique, University of Michigan, Working Paper; Carter, Michael R., Rachid Laajaj, and Dean Yang (2016), Subsidies, Savings and Sustainable Technology Adoption: Field Experimental Evidence from Mozambique, University of Michigan, Working Paper; Cunguara, Benedito, and Ika Darnhofer (2011), Assessing the Impact of Improved Agricultural Technologies on Household Income in Rural Mozambique, Food Policy, 36, pp. 378-390; Conley, Timothy G., and Christopher R. Udry (2010), Learning About a New Technology: Pineapple in Ghana, American Economic Review, 100(1), pp. 35-69; Duflo, Esther, Michael Kremer, and Jonathan Robinson (2008), How High Are Rates of Return to Fertilizer? Evidence from Field Experiments in Kenya, American Economic Review, 98(2), pp. 482-488; Duflo, Esther, Michael Kremer, and Jonathan Robinson (2011), Nudging Farmers to Use Fertilizer: Theory and Experimental Evidence from Kenya, American Economic Review, 101, pp. 2350-2390; Dupas, Pascaline, and Jonathan Robinson (2013), Savings Constraints and Microenterprise Development: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Kenya, American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 5(1), pp. 163-192; Jack, William, Adam Ray, and Tavneet Suri (2012), Transaction Networks: Evidence from Mobile Money in Kenya, American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 103(3), pp. 356-361; Jack, William, and Tavneet Suri (2011), Mobile Money: The Economics of M-PESA, NBER Working Paper No. 16721; Jack, William, and Tavneet Suri (2014), Risk Sharing and Transactions Costs: Evidence from Kenya’s Mobile Money Revolution, American Economic Review, 104(1), pp. 183-223; Jack, William, and Tavneet Suri (2016), The Long Run Poverty and Gender Impacts of Mobile Money, Science, 354(6317), pp. 1288-1292; Mbiti, Isaac, and David N. Weil (2011), Mobile Banking: The Impact of M-Pesa in Kenya, NBER Working Paper No. 17129; 24 Townsend, Robert (1994), Risk and Insurance in Village India, Econometrica, 62(3), pp. 539591; Udry, Christopher (1994), Risk and Insurance in a Rural Credit Market: An Empirical Investigation in Northern Nigeria, Review of Economic Studies, 61(3), pp. 495-526. 25 Appendix Figure 1: mKesh leaflet Front. Main operations conducted: Self-registration. Deposit. 26 Figure 2: Leaflet on fertilizer use 27 Figure 3: Leaflet on savings bonus 28 Figure 4: 2x2 experimental design Individual Treatment - I Network Treatment - N Control – C CI CN Savings Treatment – S SI SN 29 Table 1a: Primary farmers' individual characteristics - differences across treatment and control groups; for both baseline and follow-up samples baseline sample CI basic demographics agriculture female 0.100 age 43.388 born in Manica province 0.920 complete primary school 0.280 number of household members 6.820 number of children 4.340 time cultivating plot (months) 116.851 number of plots 2.220 size of main plot (hectares) 4.293 number of crops last year 2.520 land fertility (1-4) 2.900 used improved seeds for maize last year used organic fertilizer for maize last year used fertilizer for maize last year maize production last year (Kgs) maize production value last year (MZN) % maize for sale last year 0.220 0.200 0.160 2,555.789 21,050.357 0.760 savings * joint F-stat savings network network p-value 0.124 0.057 0.052 0.499 (0.085) (0.072) (0.064) 3.910 4.436* -0.127 0.165 (2.410) (2.646) (2.673) -0.048 -0.038 -0.007 0.845 (0.060) (0.060) (0.051) 0.047 -0.005 0.003 0.946 (0.100) (0.092) (0.091) 0.343 1.317 -0.711 0.054 (0.786) (0.825) (0.666) 0.742 1.738** -0.557 0.013 (0.667) (0.732) (0.624) 34.924 16.443 29.460 0.462 (22.854) (21.462) (25.010) -0.077 -0.220 -0.437* 0.340 (0.282) (0.216) (0.259) -0.508 0.763 -0.091 0.527 (0.670) (0.996) (0.765) 0.092 -0.108 0.176 0.701 (0.267) (0.267) (0.283) -0.063 -0.057 -0.117 0.905 (0.127) (0.128) (0.160) 0.127 0.172 0.193* 0.292 (0.095) (0.112) (0.111) 0.147 0.035 0.104 0.330 (0.094) (0.090) (0.098) -0.058 0.016 0.014 0.475 (0.067) (0.075) (0.068) 287.589 178.655 27.446 0.965 (559.173) (566.536) (577.998) 2,466.071 2,365.310 10,570.512 0.818 (7,920.370) (6,615.428) (11,176.000) 0.036 0.044 0.044 0.918 (0.074) (0.074) (0.084) follow-up sample CI 0.045 44.568 0.909 0.273 6.864 4.568 122.595 2.114 4.329 2.386 2.909 0.250 0.205 0.182 2,662.222 21,780.400 0.750 savings * joint F-stat network p-value 0.167** 0.111* 0.091 0.132 (0.082) (0.067) (0.067) 2.810 3.255 -0.318 0.379 (2.506) (2.757) (2.814) -0.020 -0.027 -0.000 0.966 (0.064) (0.064) (0.056) 0.046 0.002 0.000 0.949 (0.101) (0.092) (0.095) 0.434 1.274 -0.614 0.065 (0.820) (0.881) (0.658) 0.602 1.510* -0.636 0.026 (0.736) (0.776) (0.649) 27.469 10.699 28.847 0.618 (24.143) (22.559) (26.912) 0.057 -0.114 -0.295 0.551 (0.275) (0.290) (0.222) -0.504 0.728 -0.073 0.564 (0.727) (1.031) (0.826) 0.273 0.025 0.295 0.637 (0.329) (0.261) (0.280) -0.079 -0.066 -0.136 0.878 (0.137) (0.138) (0.171) 0.112 0.142 0.182 0.443 (0.099) (0.116) (0.118) 0.136 0.031 0.114 0.362 (0.098) (0.095) (0.105) -0.075 -0.005 -0.000 0.502 (0.071) (0.078) (0.072) 237.921 72.222 -73.434 0.978 (584.756) (576.931) (598.421) 2,295.896 1,635.267 9,840.470 0.859 (8,447.872) (7,083.919) (11,358.225) 0.059 0.054 0.045 0.856 (0.072) (0.077) (0.089) savings network Note: Standard errors of the differences reported in parenthesis; standard errors are corrected by clustering at the location level. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. 30 Table 1b: Primary farmers' individual characteristics - differences across treatment and control groups; for both baseline and follow-up samples baseline sample CI has bank account 0.260 time having a bank account (months) 79.154 contributes to a saving group 0.140 number of saving groups 2.143 time contributing to saving groups (months) 48.857 saving at home 0.820 total expenditure (MZN/month) 1,407.204 owns barn 0.880 owns fridge 0.040 owns sewing machine 0.200 owns radio 0.820 owns tv 0.429 owns bike 0.700 owns motorcycle 0.100 owns generator 0.060 owns animals 0.900 owns pump 0.020 owns improved latrine 0.245 has access to electricity 0.280 has access to piped water or protected spring 0.500 savings expenditure and assets savings network 0.128 (0.094) -28.321 (29.651) 0.044 (0.064) -0.921 (0.998) -18.302 (19.522) -0.106 (0.087) 261.097 (479.768) 0.059 (0.049) 0.062 (0.050) -0.016 (0.086) -0.004 (0.069) 0.020 (0.104) -0.027 (0.099) -0.018 (0.066) 0.062 (0.060) 0.018 (0.060) -0.020 (0.020) 0.020 (0.098) 0.026 (0.089) 0.031 (0.105) 0.054 (0.071) -10.621 (39.861) 0.036 (0.077) -1.032 (1.005) -17.857 (18.080) -0.140 (0.085) 589.231 (411.227) 0.061 (0.055) -0.020 (0.034) -0.020 (0.096) 0.060 (0.073) -0.109 (0.098) -0.140 (0.093) 0.080 (0.077) 0.020 (0.051) 0.000 (0.062) -0.020 (0.020) -0.025 (0.098) 0.020 (0.090) 0.040 (0.100) follow-up sample savings * network 0.066 (0.077) -14.354 (34.955) 0.012 (0.054) -1.000 (0.869) -21.143 (18.092) 0.024 (0.066) -109.973 (290.928) 0.077 (0.051) 0.003 (0.040) -0.004 (0.086) 0.071 (0.081) -0.016 (0.106) 0.061 (0.079) 0.030 (0.055) 0.070 (0.045) -0.030 (0.065) 0.023 (0.036) 0.038 (0.102) 0.003 (0.080) 0.043 (0.101) joint F-stat p-value CI 0.586 0.273 0.752 82.750 0.921 0.136 0.375 2.333 0.560 50.500 0.167 0.864 0.396 1,373.589 0.417 0.864 0.372 0.045 0.994 0.159 0.695 0.841 0.581 0.364 0.183 0.682 0.361 0.068 0.226 0.045 0.862 0.886 0.209 0.023 0.929 0.273 0.991 0.250 0.969 0.523 savings network 0.132 (0.104) -31.917 (31.547) 0.034 (0.065) -1.083 (1.157) -16.875 (22.558) -0.119 (0.087) 329.716 (507.955) 0.073 (0.054) 0.040 (0.051) 0.011 (0.067) -0.032 (0.075) 0.083 (0.099) -0.001 (0.102) 0.017 (0.059) 0.082 (0.061) 0.029 (0.064) -0.023 (0.023) 0.004 (0.106) 0.048 (0.090) 0.009 (0.108) 0.041 (0.077) -14.217 (41.830) 0.040 (0.078) -1.222 (1.157) -19.500 (21.041) -0.184** (0.086) 622.845 (422.624) 0.078 (0.059) -0.025 (0.038) 0.021 (0.086) 0.039 (0.075) -0.044 (0.094) -0.122 (0.096) 0.112 (0.069) 0.035 (0.049) 0.014 (0.065) -0.023 (0.023) -0.053 (0.102) 0.050 (0.096) 0.017 (0.097) savings * network 0.068 (0.085) -17.950 (36.878) 0.023 (0.053) -1.190 (1.023) -22.786 (21.216) -0.003 (0.068) -47.557 (316.114) 0.091 (0.056) 0.000 (0.044) 0.045 (0.087) 0.045 (0.083) 0.023 (0.106) 0.068 (0.086) 0.045 (0.063) 0.068 (0.046) 0.000 (0.066) 0.023 (0.039) 0.023 (0.110) 0.045 (0.081) 0.045 (0.096) joint F-stat p-value 0.637 0.720 0.947 0.294 0.428 0.104 0.403 0.373 0.522 0.959 0.726 0.675 0.233 0.337 0.256 0.954 0.207 0.876 0.925 0.973 Note: Standard errors of the differences reported in parenthesis; standard errors are corrected by clustering at the location level. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. 31 Table 2a: mKesh use - administrative data (log) dependent variable ------> average daily savings coefficient savings - β S (H1a) standard error coefficient network - β N (H2a) standard error coefficient savings*network - β SN (H3) standard error mean dep. variable (CI group) β S + β SN = 0 (H1b) F-stat p-value β N + β SN = 0 (H2b) F-stat p-value β S + βN + β SN = 0 F-stat p-value r-squared adjusted number of observations controls first year (1) (2) 0.444** 0.376* (0.204) (0.207) -0.001 -0.059 (0.226) (0.220) -0.263 -0.115 (0.297) (0.299) 4.333 4.343 0.400 0.231 0.162 0.397 0.339 0.309 0.035 0.052 146 142 no yes second year (3) (4) 0.348 0.301 (0.281) (0.314) -0.052 -0.095 (0.309) (0.302) -0.581 -0.353 (0.462) (0.486) 4.018 4.018 0.524 0.882 0.067 0.231 0.393 0.646 0.000 0.024 144 140 no yes total value of transactions (5) 0.782* (0.458) 0.417 (0.441) -0.836 (0.608) 5.109 0.895 0.339 0.436 0.079 116 no (6) 0.837* (0.457) 0.411 (0.455) -0.852 (0.635) 5.109 0.973 0.312 0.396 0.078 115 yes average value of transactions (7) 0.633 (0.387) 0.142 (0.352) -0.712 (0.524) 2.707 0.825 0.155 0.867 -0.003 116 no (8) 0.687* (0.360) 0.088 (0.363) -0.620 (0.529) 2.707 0.858 0.162 0.683 0.041 115 yes Note: All regressions are OLS. All dependent variables are based on transaction data made available by the mKesh operator for the period between the end of the survey team visits before planting season in 2013 to the end of June 2015. Transactions include cash-ins, cash-outs, transfers sent and received, and payments; transactions that were part of the mKesh dissemination module are not included when computing total amounts transacted. All regressions include district dummies. Controls are gender, age, whether the individual was born in Manica province, whether the individual has completed primary school, number of household members, and number of children. Robust standard errors reported in parenthesis. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. Table 2b: mKesh use - administrative data (squared root) dependent variable ------> coefficient savings - β S (H1a) standard error coefficient network - β N (H2a) standard error coefficient savings*network - β SN (H3) standard error mean dep. variable (CI group) β S + β SN = 0 (H1b) F-stat p-value β N + β SN = 0 (H2b) F-stat p-value β S + βN + β SN = 0 F-stat p-value r-squared adjusted number of observations controls total value of cash-ins (1) 1.494 (2.243) 1.470 (2.680) -3.393 (3.422) 6.338 0.456 0.351 0.834 0.117 196 no (2) 1.528 (2.370) 1.285 (2.814) -3.453 (3.605) 6.467 0.466 0.314 0.761 0.098 191 yes total value of top-ups (3) -0.220 (0.983) 1.268 (1.255) -0.595 (1.665) 2.952 0.544 0.536 0.694 0.214 196 no (4) 0.275 (1.058) 1.715 (1.380) -1.615 (1.869) 3.012 0.361 0.930 0.753 0.216 191 yes total value of transfers received (5) (6) 2.739*** 3.125*** (0.849) (0.916) 0.455 0.586 (0.532) (0.617) 0.943 0.485 (1.580) (1.756) 0.000 0.000 0.008 0.016 0.347 0.493 0.003 0.003 0.221 0.215 196 191 no yes total value of transfers sent (7) (8) 0.067 -0.007 (0.138) (0.194) 1.237 1.169 (0.843) (0.849) -0.208 -0.095 (1.076) (1.113) 0.000 0.000 0.892 0.923 0.077 0.079 0.066 0.076 0.032 0.010 196 191 no yes total value of payments (9) 0.313 (0.290) 0.061 (0.243) -0.540* (0.324) 0.172 0.180 0.045 0.350 0.001 196 no (10) 0.330 (0.342) 0.105 (0.304) -0.668 (0.450) 0.176 0.113 0.047 0.247 0.029 191 yes total value of cash-outs (11) 0.343 (2.144) -0.294 (2.311) -0.183 (3.240) 6.019 0.948 0.832 0.953 0.072 196 no (12) 0.600 (2.290) -0.155 (2.490) -0.626 (3.494) 6.142 0.992 0.738 0.938 0.055 191 yes Note: All regressions are OLS. All dependent variables are based on transaction data made available by the mKesh operator for the period between the end of the survey team visits before planting season in 2013 to the end of June 2015. Transactions that were part of the mKesh dissemination module are not included when computing total amounts transacted. All regressions include district dummies. Controls are gender, age, whether the individual was born in Manica province, whether the individual has completed primary school, number of household members, and number of children. Robust standard errors reported in parenthesis. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. 32 Table 3: Maize sold and fertilizer received through the survey team dependent variable ------> coefficient savings - β S (H1a) standard error coefficient network - β N (H2a) standard error coefficient savings*network - β SN (H3) standard error mean dep. variable (CI group) β S + β SN = 0 (H1b) F-stat p-value β N + β SN = 0 (H2b) F-stat p-value β S + βN + β SN = 0 F-stat p-value r-squared adjusted number of observations controls whether maize was sold through the survey team (1) 0.019 (0.057) 0.144** (0.062) -0.103 (0.083) 0.119 0.162 0.455 0.333 0.439 176 no (2) 0.041 (0.060) 0.152** (0.066) -0.126 (0.090) 0.119 0.174 0.651 0.286 0.442 173 yes % maize value sold through the survey team using mKesh (3) 0.771*** (0.154) 0.003 (0.003) 0.059 (0.189) 0.000 0.000 0.747 0.000 0.815 27 no (4) 0.917*** (0.179) 0.055 (0.098) -0.105 (0.241) 0.000 0.000 0.849 0.000 0.776 27 yes whether fertilizer was purchased through the survey team (5) 0.044 (0.047) 0.007 (0.040) -0.009 (0.063) 0.026 0.422 0.973 0.359 -0.001 174 no (6) 0.054 (0.049) 0.010 (0.036) -0.021 (0.063) 0.026 0.467 0.833 0.355 -0.030 170 yes Note: All regressions are OLS. All dependent variables are based on transaction data registered by the survey team during all visits before planting season. All regressions include district dummies. Controls are gender, age, whether the individual was born in Manica province, whether the individual has completed primary school, number of household members, and number of children. Robust standard errors reported in parenthesis. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. 33 Table 4a: Savings definition dependent variable ------> coefficient savings - β S (H1a) standard error coefficient network - β N (H2a) standard error coefficient savings*network - β SN (H3) standard error mean dep. variable (CI group) β S + β SN = 0 (H1b) F-stat p-value β N + β SN = 0 (H2b) F-stat p-value β S + βN + β SN = 0 F-stat p-value r-squared adjusted number of observations controls when asked about definition of savings mentioned plan and wise spending when asked about definition of savings mentioned friends' help (1) 0.105** (0.046) 0.059* (0.033) -0.091 (0.069) 0.000 0.786 0.614 0.076 0.000 181 no (3) 0.066* (0.036) 0.004 (0.006) -0.072* (0.040) 0.000 0.401 0.072 0.738 0.055 181 no (2) 0.097** (0.048) 0.063* (0.034) -0.083 (0.067) 0.000 0.799 0.740 0.076 -0.026 177 yes (4) 0.064* (0.035) -0.008 (0.011) -0.058* (0.034) 0.000 0.574 0.063 0.799 0.091 177 yes Note: All regressions are OLS. All dependent variables are based on transaction data registered by the survey team during all visits before planting season. All regressions include district dummies. Controls are gender, age, whether the individual was born in Manica province, whether the individual has completed primary school, number of household members, and number of children. Robust standard errors reported in parenthesis. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. Table 4b: Saving methods beyond mKesh - extensive margin dependent variable ------> coefficient savings - β S (H1a) standard error coefficient network - β N (H2a) standard error coefficient savings*network - β SN (H3) standard error mean dep. variable (CI group) β S + β SN = 0 (H1b) F-stat p-value β N + β SN = 0 (H2b) F-stat p-value β S + βN + β SN = 0 F-stat p-value r-squared adjusted number of observations controls difference-in-differences fixed effects saving at home (1) 0.161 (0.121) 0.135 (0.125) -0.351** (0.177) 0.785 0.141 0.085 0.658 0.034 371 yes yes no (2) 0.136 (0.112) 0.156 (0.127) -0.342** (0.166) 0.777 0.095 0.082 0.660 0.028 380 no yes yes saving in bank account (3) -0.030 (0.132) 0.064 (0.125) 0.008 (0.190) 0.247 0.872 0.614 0.751 0.053 373 yes yes no (4) -0.021 (0.059) 0.059 (0.069) -0.015 (0.099) 0.245 0.650 0.536 0.765 0.000 382 no yes yes saving with shopkeeper (5) -0.157** (0.071) -0.085 (0.060) 0.242** (0.101) 0.043 0.229 0.052 0.986 0.012 373 yes yes no (6) -0.152** (0.064) -0.085 (0.060) 0.237** (0.093) 0.043 0.215 0.036 1.000 0.032 382 no yes yes saving in gold (7) -0.069 (0.058) -0.084* (0.051) 0.086 (0.080) 0.032 0.753 0.977 0.244 -0.002 373 yes yes no (8) -0.065 (0.058) -0.082 (0.052) 0.079 (0.081) 0.032 0.812 0.963 0.258 0.016 382 no yes yes saving in animals (9) -0.094 (0.091) -0.160* (0.088) 0.314** (0.129) 0.086 0.017 0.102 0.508 0.019 373 yes yes no (10) -0.091 (0.093) -0.150* (0.091) 0.309** (0.134) 0.085 0.026 0.109 0.478 0.031 382 no yes yes Note: All regressions are OLS. All dependent variables are based on survey questions asked in both the follow-up and baseline surveys. All regressions without fixed effects include district dummies. Controls are gender, age, whether the individual was born in Manica province, whether the individual has completed primary school, number of household members, and number of children. Robust standard errors reported in parenthesis. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. 34 Table 4c: Saving methods beyond mKesh - intensive margin (log) dependent variable ------> coefficient savings - β S (H1a) standard error coefficient network - β N (H2a) standard error coefficient savings*network - β SN (H3) standard error mean dep. variable (CI group) β S + β SN = 0 (H1b) F-stat p-value β N + β SN = 0 (H2b) F-stat p-value β S + βN + β SN = 0 F-stat p-value r-squared adjusted number of observations controls difference-in-differences fixed effects saving at home (1) -0.212 (0.334) -0.606** (0.308) 0.272 (0.476) 7.290 0.863 0.362 0.119 0.052 133 no no no (2) -0.329 (0.302) -0.822*** (0.296) 0.805* (0.444) 7.290 0.145 0.958 0.289 0.245 132 yes no no saving in bank account (3) 0.393 (0.865) 0.269 (0.911) 0.411 (0.958) 7.613 0.176 0.190 0.261 -0.038 61 no no no (4) 0.675 (0.851) 0.225 (0.925) 0.333 (0.942) 7.613 0.164 0.274 0.229 -0.044 59 yes no no overall savings (aggregate) (5) (6) 0.199 0.119 (0.478) (0.471) -1.066* -1.381** (0.572) (0.543) 1.107 1.691** (0.795) (0.793) 7.665 7.665 0.046 0.006 0.940 0.591 0.679 0.454 0.017 0.099 166 163 no yes no no no no Note: All regressions are OLS. All dependent variables are based on survey questions asked in both the follow-up and baseline surveys. All regressions without fixed effects include district dummies. Controls are gender, age, whether the individual was born in Manica province, whether the individual has completed primary school, number of household members, and number of children. Robust standard errors reported in parenthesis. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. 35 Table 5: Agricultural inputs dependent variable ------> coefficient savings - β S (H1a) standard error coefficient network - β N (H2a) standard error coefficient savings*network - β SN (H3) standard error mean dep. variable (CI group) β S + β SN = 0 (H1b) F-stat p-value β N + β SN = 0 (H2b) F-stat p-value β S + βN + β SN = 0 F-stat p-value r-squared adjusted number of observations controls difference-in-differences fixed effects fertilizer (1) 0.311*** (0.117) -0.143 (0.105) 0.095 (0.164) 0.194 0.000 0.701 0.033 0.167 373 yes yes no (2) 0.359*** (0.091) -0.124 (0.078) 0.038 (0.136) 0.191 0.000 0.439 0.008 0.238 382 no yes yes kgs fertilizer (3) 12.107 (29.687) 5.611 (28.525) -12.652 (48.759) 46.000 0.988 0.844 0.865 0.021 49 no no no (4) 25.322 (36.633) 20.043 (33.351) -16.825 (53.767) 46.000 0.824 0.935 0.491 -0.030 47 yes no no knowledge about using urea fertilizer (5) (6) 0.154* 0.175** (0.080) (0.078) -0.084 -0.059 (0.076) (0.075) -0.044 -0.075 (0.112) (0.114) 0.545 0.545 0.160 0.210 0.124 0.106 0.728 0.605 0.026 0.086 184 180 no yes no no no no number of workers in farm (7) (8) 0.093 0.323 (1.344) (1.253) -0.112 -0.459 (1.339) (1.234) 0.123 0.636 (1.682) (1.558) 7.386 7.386 0.842 0.370 0.992 0.867 0.944 0.733 -0.013 0.054 186 182 no yes no no no no irrigation pumps (9) 0.069* (0.040) 0.022 (0.021) -0.090 (0.055) 0.011 0.583 0.180 0.989 -0.005 370 yes yes no (10) 0.067* (0.038) 0.023 (0.023) -0.090 (0.055) 0.011 0.566 0.183 1.000 0.012 379 no yes yes improved seeds (11) 0.028 (0.105) -0.097 (0.105) 0.146 (0.147) 0.523 0.092 0.642 0.475 0.019 185 no no no (12) 0.072 (0.108) -0.033 (0.108) 0.078 (0.151) 0.523 0.135 0.654 0.277 0.091 181 yes no no organic fertilizer (13) 0.115 (0.106) 0.044 (0.104) -0.120 (0.147) 0.372 0.960 0.462 0.717 0.024 182 no no no (14) 0.154 (0.107) 0.077 (0.104) -0.194 (0.152) 0.372 0.706 0.282 0.734 0.025 178 yes no no Note: All regressions are OLS. All dependent variables are based on survey questions asked in the follow-up survey or both the follow-up and baseline surveys. All regressions without fixed effects include district dummies. Controls are gender, age, whether the individual was born in Manica province, whether the individual has completed primary school, number of household members, and number of children. Robust standard errors reported in parenthesis. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. 36 Table 6: Household expenditures (log) dependent variable ------> coefficient savings - β S (H1a) standard error coefficient network - β N (H2a) standard error coefficient savings*network - β SN (H3) standard error mean dep. variable (CI group) β S + β SN = 0 (H1b) F-stat p-value β N + β SN = 0 (H2b) F-stat p-value β S + βN + β SN = 0 F-stat p-value r-squared adjusted number of observations controls difference-in-differences fixed effects day-to-day expenditures (1) 0.243 (0.339) -0.075 (0.330) 0.125 (0.461) 6.934 0.252 0.880 0.341 0.047 308 yes yes no (2) 0.160 (0.277) -0.120 (0.276) 0.268 (0.410) 6.919 0.159 0.624 0.273 0.029 315 no yes yes non-frequent expenditures (3) (4) 0.350 0.565* (0.374) (0.337) -0.194 -0.236 (0.337) (0.346) 0.479 0.319 (0.526) (0.490) 5.592 5.580 0.027 0.014 0.484 0.810 0.083 0.062 0.220 0.356 328 334 yes no yes yes no yes total expenditures (5) 0.581* (0.330) -0.095 (0.309) 0.026 (0.449) 7.045 0.049 0.832 0.100 0.166 353 yes yes no (6) 0.638** (0.299) -0.103 (0.268) -0.023 (0.397) 7.034 0.019 0.666 0.075 0.320 360 no yes yes Note: All regressions are OLS. All dependent variables are based on survey questions asked in both the follow-up and baseline surveys. All regressions without fixed effects include district dummies. Controls are gender, age, whether the individual was born in Manica province, whether the individual has completed primary school, number of household members, and number of children. Robust standard errors reported in parenthesis. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. 37 Table 7: Lending/borrowing and transfer amounts dependent variable ------> coefficient savings - β S (H1a) standard error coefficient network - β N (H2a) standard error coefficient savings*network - β SN (H3) standard error mean dep. variable (CI group) β S + β SN = 0 (H1b) F-stat p-value β N + β SN = 0 (H2b) F-stat p-value β S + βN + β SN = 0 F-stat p-value r-squared adjusted number of observations controls lent to closest farming friends (1) -0.032 (0.064) -0.093 (0.063) 0.163* (0.089) 0.193 0.035 0.261 0.572 0.013 186 no (2) -0.012 (0.068) -0.083 (0.064) 0.129 (0.093) 0.193 0.067 0.474 0.618 0.010 182 yes log amount transfers sent (3) -0.456 (1.315) -0.550 (1.196) 0.267 (1.454) 7.637 0.770 0.720 0.526 -0.208 21 no (4) -0.760 (2.029) -2.059* (1.174) 1.255 (2.265) 7.637 0.571 0.678 0.186 -0.218 21 yes lent to closest farming friends for current consumption (5) -0.013 (0.243) -0.152 (0.263) 0.447 (0.340) 0.400 0.077 0.204 0.201 0.083 36 no (6) 0.166 (0.236) -0.057 (0.259) 0.167 (0.359) 0.400 0.175 0.650 0.196 0.238 36 yes borrowed from closest farming friends log amount transfers received borrowed from closest farming friends for current consumption (7) -0.104* (0.055) -0.092 (0.056) 0.286*** (0.082) 0.170 0.003 0.001 0.190 0.061 186 no (9) -0.117 (1.019) -0.735 (1.022) 0.002 (1.272) 7.453 0.879 0.325 0.433 -0.112 29 no (11) -0.846*** (0.177) -0.516** (0.250) 1.180*** (0.285) 0.750 0.161 0.000 0.361 0.221 34 no (8) -0.087 (0.055) -0.063 (0.055) 0.246*** (0.079) 0.170 0.007 0.002 0.155 0.087 182 yes (10) -0.155 (1.079) -1.577 (1.115) 0.387 (1.363) 7.453 0.763 0.121 0.216 -0.143 27 yes (12) -1.124*** (0.311) -0.378 (0.343) 1.256** (0.502) 0.750 0.714 0.009 0.269 0.189 33 yes Note: All regressions are OLS. Dependent variables are based on survey questions asked in the follow-up survey. The dependent variables in regressions (1)-(2) and (9)-(10) take value 1 if both friends were lent or borrowed by/from the individual; they take value 0.5 if just one friend was lent or borrowed; they take value 0 if no friend was lent or borrowed. The remaining dependent variables are binary except log amounts. All regressions include district dummies. Controls are gender, age, whether the individual was born in Manica province, whether the individual has completed primary school, number of household members, and number of children. Robust standard errors reported in parenthesis. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. 38
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz