CEP 4-18 Product Differentiation, Firm Size, and Entry Richard L. Carson January 2017 CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS Department of Economics 1125 Colonel By Drive Ottawa, Ontario, Canada K1S 5B6 PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION, FIRM SIZE, and ENTRY Richard L. Carson Carleton University ABSTRACT Using the ability of substitute products to constrain a firm’s pricing and output, this note gives a method of determining the long-run equilibrium output of a firm operating under imperfect competition that differs from standard methods of output determination and reveals properties of the equilibrium that standard methods conceal. Under weak assumptions, a policy of free entry and exit is optimal even though all-around marginal-cost pricing does not prevail. Under monopolistic competition, firm size will not be too small, nor will the supplier of X have excess capacity. JEL Classifications: D24, D43, D61. Key Words: Imperfect Competition, Substitutability, Cost Effectiveness, Firm Size, Excess Capacity. 1 PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION, FIRM SIZE, and ENTRY I. Introduction This note gives a method of finding the long-run equilibrium output of a firm operating under imperfect competition—specifically under monopolistic competition or oligopoly—that differs from standard methods of output determination and reveals properties of the equilibrium that standard methods conceal.1 Let X be a product supplied by a firm under imperfect competition, with long-run general equilibrium output, xe, and suppose there is a related good, Y, sold under perfect competition or at least under competitive pricing, with price equal to minimum average cost in equilibrium.2 For example, X might be a differentiated version of a good or service and Y a generic version. When two basic conditions are met, xe will be where the average cost of Y reaches its minimum or where the production function for Y displays constant returns to scale. This is true as long as X and Y are viable and the basic conditions hold. Differentiating a product does not change its long-run equilibrium output at the level of the firm, which is entirely determined by technical properties of the production function for the competitive good Y. It will also be argued that the production function for X displays constant or decreasing returns to scale at xe, even though the rent-inclusive average cost of X is falling as output expands. In this case, firm size is not too small nor is there excess capacity. Moreover, a policy of free entry and exit will be optimal even though allaround marginal-cost pricing does not prevail. The reason is that marginal firms will price at or near marginal cost, and the long-run equilibrium outputs of infra-marginal firms will be sticky in the face of shifts in product demand. In what follows, we first set out basic assumptions and then use these to derive basic results. Next we relax one of these assumptions to show how the outcome is changed. Finally, the question of entry is dealt with. A concluding section summarizes results. 2 II. Assumptions Let Px and Py be the demand prices of X and Y and x be the output of X by the supplier of this good. X and Y are assumed to be measured in the same well-defined output units, and with x plotted on the horizontal axis, ACy is the long-run average cost of Y that a supplier of Y would face. It is assumed to take the conventional U shape, with a minimum at x = x*. Let ACRx be the “rent-inclusive” long-run average cost of x. This is long-run average cost inclusive of all rents earned in the supply of X that persist over the long run. These include the rent to the supplier’s market position, when this is protected by entry barriers, as well as earnings of product-specialized inputs over and above the opportunity costs of these inputs in supplying other goods. If all inputs are mobile between firms—including alternative possible suppliers of X—the latter rents are part of the opportunity cost of a firm supplying X. Thus when inputs are mobile between firms and market positions are freely transferable from one firm to another, rent-inclusive and opportunity costs will be the same for each firm. This is the assumption made here. A firm will then supply X over the long run if and only if it expects to be able to produce where Px ≥ ACRx, but long-run competitive pressures will also force Px ≤ ACRx to hold at each x. In long-run equilibrium, the firm supplying X therefore maximizes profit where Px = ACRx—and thus where its demand is tangent to downward-sloping ACRx—and the firm supplying Y maximizes profit where Py = ACy = MCy, where MCy is the marginal cost of Y. The outcomes, Px > ACRx or Py > ACy, can occur only in the short run when sellers are able to earn disequilibrium or entrepreneurial profits (quasi-rents) that attract entry and are competed away over the long run via expansion of supply by competitors. Production of X is assumed to use product-specialized inputs, which add value to X, but are not used to produce Y. Let Fx be a fixed cost of X in the form of rent to the supplier’s market position and to its productspecialized inputs. Then ACRx = ACx + Fx/x, where ACx is the average cost of X, exclusive of this rent. (In general, ACx and ACy are not the same.) A differentiated product is assumed to possess unique attributes, features, or properties whose cost-effective supply requires inputs specialized to these unique elements and thus to the product. For example, suppose a restaurant supplies cuisine with a unique flavor and ambience. Its 3 product-specialized inputs are its recipes, together with the tacit knowledge and the talent—embodied in a master chef and his/her team—used to create the cuisine from the recipes. These inputs could be bought by another owner which would then acquire the unique cuisine in question. Thus the rent earned by these productspecialized inputs is part of the opportunity cost of the restaurant supplying the cuisine that they produce. The recipes, tacit knowledge, and talent in question are fixed stocks, and their remuneration is therefore a cost that is fixed or “quasi-fixed”, in the sense that it does not vary with output once a decision has been taken to produce a product. Because production of X uses product-specialized inputs that are not used to produce Y and because the supplier of X may be able to exercise market power, Px > Py will hold. In long-run general equilibrium, (Px Py) ≥ (ACRx ACy) must also hold for the firm supplying X if ACRx and ACy are evaluated at x = xe. Since Px = ACRx in equilibrium, (Px Py) < (ACRx ACy) would imply that Py > ACy is possible. In general, either (Px Py) > (ACRx ACy) or (Px Py) = (ACRx ACy) can hold, equality implying that xe = x*. Figures (a) and (b) illustrate these possibilities. In Figure (a), the equilibrium price and output of X are assumed to be at E1 where xe < x* and (Px Py) > (ACRx ACy). In Figure (b), equilibrium price and output are at E2, where xe = x*, and thus (Px Py) = (ACRx ACy). For example, in traditional monopolistic competition [Chamberlin 1933], E1 and E2 are two possible points of tangency between demand and ACRx. We shall argue below that in an economy with free entry and exit, E2 is the more likely outcome. In the context above, one could say that the supplier of X adds value to Y internally, within its production process, by adding quality. However, a firm could also add value to Y externally by supplying a third product, Z, that is used with Y. For example, let Y be a generic bread with a bland taste and X be a differentiated bread with a unique taste. Suppose an entrepreneur markets a spread, Z, that improves the taste of the generic bread, but clashes with the taste of the differentiated bread. Then the combination of generic bread with spread will compete with the differentiated bread. If both X and Y survive in long-run equilibrium, the basic assumption of this paper says that at least one product, Z, is also viable over the long-run that meets two conditions—a substitutability condition and a cost-effectiveness condition. 4 5 The substitutability condition requires Z and X to be substitutes in demand, given the presence of Y (although not necessarily otherwise). Let the Z industry and the X industry denote the industries in which the suppliers of these two products operate. Then an expansion of supply in the Z industry that reduces Pz, the demand price of Z at any given output, z, is also assumed to reduce Px at any given x. Likewise, an expansion of supply in the X industry that reduces Px at any given x is assumed to lower Pz as well at any given z. Most products face competition from outside the immediate industry in which they operate. By itself, therefore, the substitutability condition is not an overly strong requirement. The cost-effectiveness condition says that a supplier of Z adds value to Y at least as cost effectively as the supplier of X. Let Z have rent-inclusive average cost, ACRz, defined as for X above. At any given x, the quality increase from Y raises price by (Px Py) and rent-inclusive average cost by (ACRx ACy). To be at least as cost effective in adding value to Y as is the supplier of X, a supplier of Z must be able to produce an output scaled to have a price equal to (Px Py) at a rent-inclusive average cost no greater than (ACRx ACy). More precisely, suppose the supplier of X is producing an output, x0, which can be any output. Then a supplier of Z will be said to be at least as cost effective in adding value to Y as the supplier of X, provided at least one output, z0, exists such that: ACRz ≤ (ACRx ACy) (1). whenever Px ≤ ACRx if z is scaled in such a way that Pz = (Px Py). Here Px, ACRx, ACy, Pz, and ACRz are all evaluated at x = x0 and z = z0. For every x0, there is assumed to be at least one such z0. Under free entry and exit, a product is likely to exist that meets both conditions. Suppose that Z meets the substitutability condition, but not necessarily the cost-effectiveness condition. Suppose that another product, T, meets the cost-effectiveness condition, but not necessarily the substitutability condition. If output units of T are scaled in such a way that its price, Pt, equals (Px Py), which in turn equals Pz, suppose that Z does not meet the cost-effectiveness condition. But then Pz = Pt = ACRt ≤ (ACRx ACy) < ACRz, and Z cannot survive in long-run equilibrium. Thus if any product, T, that is viable in long-run equilibrium meets the costeffectiveness condition, all viable products other than X and Y must meet this condition, including products that 6 meet the substitutability condition. Given the lack of restrictions on T, a product, Z, that meets both conditions is likely to be viable in long-run equilibrium under conditions of all-around free entry and exit. Then fewer resources will be crowded into the sector of non-differentiated products that are priced competitively and more resources will be in the sector of differentiated products than when the differentiated sector is protected by entry barriers. III. Basic Results Assume that a product, Z, is available that meets both the substitutability and the cost-effectiveness conditions. Then the supplier of X must produce on a scale that is efficient for Y in order to cost compete with the composite good whose units consist of a unit of Z plus a unit of Y and whose average cost equals (ACRz + Py). To see this, suppose that x is set where Px = ACRx and where (Px Py) > (ACRx ACy) or, equivalently, ACy > Py as in Figure (a). But then long-run general equilibrium cannot prevail, since (1) implies that a supplier of Z can produce where Pz > ACRz. As a result, the prospect of quasi-rents will attract entry of new competitors into the Z industry, and this additional competition will generate downward pressure on Pz and Px. When Pz = ACRz is reached, Px < ACRx must also hold if the supplier of X is still producing where ACy > Py, since Pz = (Px Py) = ACRz ≤ (ACRx ACy) then holds as well. The supplier of X is failing to cover its opportunity cost and must therefore change its output or exit the market. If this supplier survives over the long run, it must produce where (Px Py) = (ACRx ACy) = Pz, because it is otherwise impossible for Px = ACRx to hold, together with (1) and Pz = ACRz. At any other output, the demand for X lies below ACRx, owing to competition from the Z industry and from Y. This gives xe = x*, the output at which ACy reaches its minimum value and at which: Py = MCy = ACy, (2). where MCy is the marginal cost of Y. x* is also the output at which the production function for Y exhibits constant returns to scale. Its value depends only on technical properties of that function, and the equilibrium outputs of X and Y are the same at the firm level. As a result, xe will be invariant to shifts in demand as long as 7 the supplier of X can cover its costs and at least one product is available that meets the substitutability and costeffectiveness conditions. Demand shifts will affect Px and the rent earned from supplying X, as well as the number of firms in the X industry, but not xe. Although long-run equilibrium is where ACRx is downward-sloping, ACx could still be constant or upward-sloping where x = x* = xe. Let Lex = (Px – MCx)/Px be the Lerner index of market power for X. If we measure returns to scale using ACx rather than ACRx, we remove the effect of Fx on economies of scale. When the supplier of X faces fixed input prices and uses no indivisible inputs other than those that are specialized to X, measuring returns to scale from ACx is the same as measuring them from the production function for X. If Rx denotes returns to scale in the production of X at any given output—or the percentage increase in x that results from increasing each input by one percent—Rx = ACx/MCx. At any given x, it would be reasonable to expect that production returns to scale would be at least as great for a more homogeneous version of a product as for a more differentiated version. Returns to scale increase as a product becomes more standardized and as its production process becomes more routinized. Thus ACx/MCx ≤ ACy/MCy at any given x. Suppose then that differentiating the firm’s product (supplying X rather than Y) does not raise returns to scale at any output, when these returns are measured as ACx/MCx and ACy/MCy. As a result, MCx ≥ ACx at x = xe = x*. There is no excess capacity in production of X nor is firm size too small. If fx = Fx/Pxx is the share of product-specialized rent in product value, we have: Lex ≤ fx, (3). when both Lex and fx are evaluated at xe = x*. Thus if free entry and exit leads to competitive pressures on X that are “strong”, in the sense of keeping fx low, these same pressures will ensure approximate marginal-cost pricing. The reason is that the supplier of X produces where ACx is constant or upward-sloping, reflecting constant or decreasing returns to scale in production. ACRx then slopes downward at x* solely because Fx is positive. In the simplest case, Lex equals one over the elasticity of demand for X at the profit maximum. Thus if fx is no more than 10 percent (more generally percent), the elasticity of demand will be at least 10 (more generally 1/), owing to competition from the Z industry and from Y. 8 In general, Z can be supplied under either perfect or imperfect competition, and in the latter case, a symmetrical relationship may hold between X and Z. Suppose that Z is a differentiated product and that V is a generic version of Z, which is sold under competitive pricing. Let z* be the output of Z at which ACv reaches its minimum. In the bread example, V could be a bland spread that complements the differentiated bread (X). Suppose further that when we interchange the roles of Y and V and of X and Z above, X meets the substitutability and cost-effectiveness conditions with respect to Z. Then ze = z*. IV. Further Results Suppose xe ╪ x* and let S be a product that meets the substitutability condition. Then S cannot meet the cost-effectiveness condition in long-run general equilibrium and, indeed, no product can meet it. If one product did meet this condition, suppliers of S would have to meet it as well by accepting a lower rent or else exit the market. Yet, even if no product meets the cost-effectiveness condition, the presence of products that meet the substitutability condition alone will place limits on Lex and on how far xe can depart from x*. To see this, suppose that for any output, x = x0, produced by a supplier of X, a supplier of S is able to produce an output, s = s0, at which: ACRs ≤ Kx(ACRx ACy), (1a). for some constant, Kx > 1, which does not depend on x0. Here s is scaled in such a way that Ps = (Px Py), and ACRx, ACy, and ACRs are all evaluated at x = x0 and s = s0. For every such x0, there is assumed to be at least one s0. If (ACx ACy) has a positive lower bound over all values of x at which ACRx is downward-sloping, a finite Kx for which (1a) holds will exist. In fact, there will be a range of parameter values for which (1a) holds, and Kx is chosen as the minimum value in this range. Inequality (1a) generalizes (1) and becomes (1) as Kx tends to one. From (1a), and arguing as above, xe must be where: (ACy Py) ≤ (Kx – 1)(ACRx ACy) (2a). in long-run general equilibrium. Inequality (1a) can also be derived from (2a), which generalizes (2) and becomes (2) as Kx tends to one. If two products, S1 and S2, meet the substitutability condition, with associated 9 values Kx1 and Kx2, where Kx1 < Kx2, S2 cannot survive in long-run general equilibrium. There can be only one value of Kx ≥ 1 which holds for every product meeting the substitutability condition that survives in long-run general equilibrium. Again assuming that Rx = ACx/MCx ≤ Ry = ACy/MCy at any given output, we have: Lex ≤ [fx + (Ry – 1)]/Ry = fx + (1 – fx)[(Ry – 1)/Ry] (3a). in long-run general equilibrium. Equation (3a) generalizes (3) and becomes (3) as Kx tends to one, since from (2a), Ry then tends to one as well. The right-hand side of (3a) is increasing in both fx and Ry. When xe is where Ry > 1, (3a) gives a looser constraint on Lex for any given fx than does (3). If the supplier of X maximizes profit where Px > MCx, it will produce where Ry ≥ Rx > (1 – fx). Therefore Lex can be no greater than fx plus a fraction of (Ry – 1). When xe is where Ry < 1, (3a) gives a tighter constraint on Lex than does (3). Approximate marginal-cost pricing prevails when Kx is close to one and fx is small. V. Entry Suppose that, for every product, X, supplied under oligopoly or monopolistic competition, products with the properties of Y(X) and Z(X) are supplied as well, and also that all-around free entry and exit prevail. Let MCx and ACx be valued at x = x*. Then marginal firms earn rents equal to or just above x*(MCx – ACx) and price at or just above marginal cost; this is also the outcome when there is a viable product, S(X), that meets the substitutability condition and almost meets the cost-effectiveness condition. Infra-marginal firms earn rent significantly above x*(MCx – ACx) as a share of product value and price significantly above marginal cost. However, they maintain constant or nearly constant output in the face of demand shifts that do not drive them from the market, unless these shifts drive out all products that meet both the substitutability and costeffectiveness conditions. When firms set prices above corresponding marginal costs, a policy of free entry and exit is in general not optimal [Mankiw and Whinston 1986]. The reason is that entry or exit potentially creates external effects on welfare that do not become part of the profits or losses of the entering or exiting firms. One such externality is the “business stealing” effect. Suppose that a new entrant reduces the demand for X. If this causes an output 10 decrease of x, the loss to consumers would be roughly Pxx, whereas the cost saving is MCxx, leaving a net welfare loss of (Px MCx)x that the entrant does not take into account in making its entry decision. However, there is no business-stealing effect for goods priced at marginal cost (Px MCx) nor is there any for products whose equilibrium output remains constant (x = 0) in the face of entry. Thus under the assumptions above, the business-stealing effect will be small under free entry and exit. If X survives the entry of a new competitor, xe will remain unchanged if Z(X) is present or will change by a relatively small amount if S(X) is present and Kx is close to one. If X is forced to exit, it is likely to have been earning a small amount of rent before entry occurred and therefore to have been pricing nearly at marginal cost. The second type of externality created by entry or exit is the “product diversity” effect. When entry adds a new product—which is not a perfect substitute for any product or combination of products already supplied—product variety increases. However, entry may also cause previously-existing products to disappear, which reduces product variety. If customers value variety, an increase in product diversity increases welfare, and this increase accrues as consumer surplus, but not as profit [Mankiw and Whinston, 1986, p. 54]. Entry or exit of firms facing horizontal demand does not alter product variety and therefore creates no product-diversity effects. Thus when (3) holds, firms forced out of an industry by entry are likely to cause small productdiversity effects since such firms are initially earning small amounts of rent and are therefore facing highly elastic demand. This is also true of firms on the margin of entering or staying out of an industry. Plausibly, the product-diversity effect is also subject to diminishing returns. As the diversity of products grows, the additional welfare gain from further diversity is falling. In short, free entry and exit helps to keep business-stealing and product-diversity effects small when (3) holds, and it may well be impossible to know whether the net bias is in favor of too many competitors or too few, relative to the socially optimal number.3 VI. Conclusion Given products X and Y plus a third product, Z, that meets the substitutability condition and a fourth product, T, that meets the cost-effectiveness condition, the long-run equilibrium output of X at the firm level will 11 be where the average cost of Y reaches its minimum and therefore the same as that of Y. The differentiated version of a product (X) has the same equilibrium output, xe = x*, as the non-differentiated version (Y). Equilibrium output, xe, will also be where rent-inclusive average cost (ACRx) is downward-sloping, but where rent-exclusive average cost (ACx) is constant or upward-sloping and where the production function for X displays constant or decreasing returns to scale. Firm size will not be too small, nor will the supplier of X have excess capacity. Even if a product such as T is unavailable, the existence of a product, S, that meets the substitutability condition, but not the cost-effectiveness condition, puts a limit on how far xe can depart from x* and on how far price can diverge from marginal cost. The value of x* is wholly determined by technical properties of the production function for Y. Thus when Z is available or when only S is available, but Kx is close to one, products supplied under imperfect competition will be priced approximately at marginal cost when they are marginal, in the sense that the share of product-specialized rent in product value is low. Infra-marginal firms that earn significant rent will also price significantly above marginal cost. Nevertheless, because the equilibrium outputs of such firms are sticky in the face of entry or exit, a policy of free entry and exit is efficient. NOTES 1. For surveys of models of imperfect competition, see Mansfield and Yohe [2004], Nicholson and Snyder [2012], and Shapiro [1989]. See Chamberlin [1933] for the basic model of monopolistic competition. 2. The market for Y may be more vulnerable to “hit-and-run” entry than is the market for X, which causes Y to be priced competitively, even though Y is not supplied under perfect competition. See Baumol [1982]. Also perfect competition is compatible with some product differentiation. See Rosen [1974]. 3. For further discussion of this question, including what is meant by the “socially optimal” number of firms, see Mankiw and Whinston [1986]. REFERENCES 1. Baumol, W.J. Contestable Markets: An Uprising in the Theory of Industry Structure. American Economic Review, March 1982, 72 (1), pp. 1-15. 12 2. Chamberlin, E. The Theory of Monopolistic Competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1933. 3. Mankiw, N.G. and Whinston, M.D. Free Entry and Social Inefficiency. Rand Journal of Economics, Spring 1986, 17 (1), pp. 48-58. 4. Mansfield, E. and Yohe, G. Microeconomics. New York: Norton, 11th ed., Chs. 10-13, pp. 356-493. 5. Nicholson, W. and Snyder, C. Microeconomic Theory: Basic Principles and Extensions. Mason, OH: South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning, 2012, 11th ed., Chs. 14-15, pp. 501-569. 6. Rosen, S. Hedonic Prices and Implicit Markets: Product Differentiation in Pure Competition. Journal of Political Economy, January/February 1974, 82 (1), pp. 34-55. 7. Shapiro, C. “Theories of Oligopoly Behavior.” Ch. 6 of Schmalensee, R. and Willig, R.D. Handbook of Industrial Organization. Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1989, vol. I, pp. 329-414. 13
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz