Stability Properties of the Nominal Income Targeting Rule in the Open Economy Baotai Wang* Economics Program University of Northern British Columbia 3333 University Way Prince George, British Columbia CANADA V2N 4Z9 Tel: (250)960-6489, Fax: (250)960-5545 Email: wangb@unbc.ca Abstract: Results of this study show that stability for output and inflation prevails under the nominal income targeting rule of monetary policy in a general open-economy model when the asymmetric effects of the interest rate on output and inflation and the different formations of inflation expectations are taken into the analysis. Key Words: Nominal income targeting, Inflation expectations, Phillips curve, Open economy, Economic stability JEL Classification: E52 _________________________ *The author would like to thank Tomson Ogwang and Paul Bowles for their valuable comments on this study. However, the usual disclaimer applies. 1 1. Introduction There has been a general agreement among economists and policymakers that a monetary policy should aim at stabilizing some nominal variables and that such a policy should be based on a fixed rule, rather than on discretion. Over the last few decades, many central banks have conducted monetary policy based on the rules that target either an interest rate measure, or a monetary aggregate, an aggregate price index, such as the consumer price index (CPI). Since the 1980s, the nominal income targeting approach to monetary policy, one of the possible policy rules advocated by some economists, has attracted considerable attention. The appeal of the nominal income targeting rule in terms of delivering better economic performance has been discussed in many studies. See, for example, Bean (1983), Taylor (1985), McCallum (1988, 1990), Bryant, Hooper, and Mann (1993), Feldstein and Stock (1994), Hall and Mankiw (1994), Frankel and Chinn (1995), and Ratti (1997). However, the question of whether or not nominal income targeting would result in dynamic stability for output and inflation remains in debate. Discussions on the issue, so far, have been mainly conducted within the context of the closed economy and special attention has been given to two factors: the stylized fact that the interest rate affects output before inflation and the formation of backward-looking inflation expectations, because they are found to be directly responsible for the instability results in the closed economy. Detailed discussions in this regard can be found in Ball (1999a), Svensson (1997), McCallum (1997), and Dennis (2001). 2 The objective of this study is to extend the discussions to the open-economy case. To this end, Ball’s (1999b) open-economy model is modified and used to examine the stability properties of the nominal income targeting rule under different conditions. The main finding of this study is that the nominal income targeting rule does not necessarily lead to instability for output and inflation in the open economy although both forementioned factors are taken into the analysis. Our results also show that different formations of inflation expectations do not change the stability conditions for the policy rule in such a model. The rest of the paper is structured as follows. In Section 2, we discuss the openeconomy model. In Section 3, we examine the stability conditions for the nominal income targeting rule with backward-looking inflation expectations. In Section 4, we replace backward-looking inflation expectations by forward-looking inflation expectations and discuss the stability conditions. In Section 5, we discuss some implications from our results. Concluding remarks are made in the last section. 2. The Model The open-economy model, which is used to examine the stability properties of the nominal income targeting rule, is specified as: yt 1 yt 1 2 rt 1 3 et t , 1 1 0, 2 0, 3 0 (1) t t 1 1 yt 1 2 et t , 1 0, 2 0 (2) et 1rt 1 t , 1 0 (3) 3 where y denotes the output gap (in logarithm); , r , and e denote, respectively, the inflation rate, the real interest rate, and the rate of real appreciation, all measured as deviations from equilibrium levels; , , and are white-noise disturbances. This model captures the basic assumptions made in Ball’s models (1999a, 1999b). Equation (1) is the open-economy IS curve. It is assumed that current output depends on its one-period lagged value and that the Marshall-Lerner condition is satisfied so that the quantity of net exports, and thereby the quantity of equilibrium output, is decreasing in the rate of real appreciation. Equation (2) is the open-economy accelerationist Phillips curve where inflation expectations are backward-looking type. Equations (1) and (2) together characterize the timing with which real interest rate affects output and inflation. Output is determined by the one-period lagged interest rate while inflation is determined, through output, by the two-period lagged interest rate. The important difference between this model and the one specified in Ball (1999b), however, is that the current rate of real appreciation, rather than a lagged one, is introduced in both demand and supply equations as the prices seen by the consumers and producers are influenced directly by the current prices of imported goods. Equation (3) closes the model by linking the rate of real appreciation to the real interest rate and it is assumed that real appreciation takes time to adjust. 3. Stability in the Open-Economy Model with Backward-looking Expectations Using the model presented in Section 2, we now examine the stability conditions for the nominal income targeting rule. 4 Substituting (3) into (1) and (2) yields a two-equation system: yt 1 yt 1 ( 2 3 1 )rt 1 ut (4) t t 1 1 yt 1 2 1rt 1 wt (5) where ut t 3 t and wt t 2 t are white noises since both are N (0, ) . The monetary authority is assumed to conduct policies by manipulating the real interest rate through its control over the nominal interest rate upon its backward-looking forecast on future inflation to achieve its objective of a constant growth rate of nominal income. For simplicity, this expected growth rate is set to be zero, i.e., Et 1 ( yt yt 1 t ) 0 , (6) where E is the expectation operator. The Taylor-style optimal interest rate rule (Taylor, 1993) can then be derived by substituting (4) and (5) into (6), rt 1 1 1 1 1 yt 1 t 1 . 2 3 1 2 1 2 3 1 2 1 (7) Substituting (7) back to (4) and (5), we derive the following reduced form of the model, yt 1 2 1 (1 1 )( 2 3 1 ) 2 3 1 yt 1 t 1 ut 2 3 1 2 1 2 3 1 2 1 (8) t (1 1 ) 2 1 1 ( 2 3 1 ) 2 3 1 yt 1 t 1 wt , 2 3 1 2 1 2 3 1 2 1 (9) which is clearly a VAR(1) system. Using capital letters A, B , and C to denote the combined coefficients in (8) and (9), we can rewrite the VAR(1) system as yt A C yt 1 ut B C w t 1 t t (10) 5 From the restrictions on the values of the model parameters imposed in Equations (1), (2), and (3), it can be easily verified that A 1 , A B 1 , and 0 C 1 . Stability of this system depends on the values of the characteristic roots of the coefficient matrix.1 Given the coefficient matrix in (10), the characteristic roots, z , are derived as: z 2 ( A C ) z ( AC BC ) 0 . (11) According Young’s lemma (Young, 1971, pp.171-172)2, the necessary and sufficient conditions for both roots being less than 1 in absolute value, which are equivalent to the conditions for system stability, are AC BC 1 and A C 1 ( AC BC ) . Since A B 1 and 0 C 1 , the first condition for stability, AC BC 1, is automatically satisfied regardless of what positive values these model parameters in C take. The second condition, A C 1 ( AC BC ) , implies (1 2C ) A 1 . Thus, stability for both output and inflation under nominal income targeting prevails in this open-economy model as long as the value of the combined coefficient A falls into this range. 4. Stability in the Open-Economy Model with Forward-looking Expectations We now discuss the stability properties of nominal income targeting in the case of forward-looking inflation expectations. To do so, the Phillips cure in the open-economy 1 See, Fomby, T.B., R.C. Hill, and S.R. Johnson (1984, p.536). 2 Young’s lemma states: For real equation x sx t 0 , the roots 2 t 1 and s 1 t . 6 x such that x 1 if and only if model (Equation (2)) is revised by changing the backward-looking inflation expectations to forward-looking inflation expectations. The revised Phillips curve is now written as t Et 1 t 1 1 yt 1 2 et t , 1 0, 2 0 (12) i.e., inflation in period t depends on expected inflation for period t 1 but expectations are formed in period t 1. This specification is consistent with models discussed in McCallum (1997) and Dennis (2001). In this case policy instrument, the Taylor-style optimal interest rate, is derived from forward-looking expectations once the growth target is set. Again, substituting (3) into (1) and (12), imposing the growth target for nominal income (6), and putting back the derived Taylor-style interest rate into the model, we obtain the following two-equation system, yt Ayt 1 CEt 1 t 1 ut , (13) t By t 1 CEt 1 t 1 wt , (14) where combined coefficients A , B , and C are identical to those in the previous section. Since the relevant state variables in the system of (13) and (14) are y t 1 , u t , and wt , we may posit the model solution, based on the minimum-state-variable (MSV) approach developed in McCallum (1983), as yt 11 yt 1 12ut 13 wt , (15) t 21 yt 1 22ut 23 wt . (16) Equation (15) and (16) clearly show that stability for output and inflation depends only on parameter 11 because if 1 11 1 holds then (15) implies output stability since u t and wt are white-noise shocks, and if output is stable then (16) implies inflation stability. 7 Applying expectations operation to (16) and updating the result one period yields Et 1 t 1 21 yt 11 21 yt 1 12 21ut 13 21wt . Substituting this into (13) and (14) and equating them to (15) and (16) respectfully, we obtain 11 yt 1 12ut 13 wt ( A C11 21 ) yt 1 (C12 21 1)ut C13 21wt , (17) 21 yt 1 22ut 23 wt ( B C11 21 ) yt 1 C12 21ut (C13 21 1)wt . (18) Equations (17) and (18) imply the undermined-coefficient requirements for the system: 11 A C1121 , 12 (C1221 1) , 13 C13 21 , 21 B C1121 , 22 C1221 , 23 C13 21 1 . Since u t and wt the white-noise disturbances, their coefficients do not affect stability and thus need not to be considered. Using 11 A C1121 and 21 B C1121 , we can solve for 11 , the key parameter responsible for model stability, 11 (1 C ) (1 C ) 2 4 AC . 2C (19) Equation (19) provides an example of non-uniqueness in the rational expectations models. For a unique solution, we follow McCallum (1997) and Dennis (2001) to choose the negative term, (1 C ) 2 4 AC , based upon the MSV criteria developed in McCallum (1983, pp.146-7). The relevant condition for stability therefore requires 1 (1 C ) (1 C ) 2 4 AC 1. 2C (20) Upon simple re-arrangement of (20), it can be verified that for any C such that 0 C 1 , (20) will hold if (1 2C ) A 1 , i.e., stability prevails and the stability conditions are exactly the same as those for the previous case. 8 5. Policy Implications The analysis presented in the last two sections indicate that, subject to certain conditions, stability for output and inflation prevails in this open-economy model under a policy of nominal income targeting. A careful inspection of these conditions provides some interesting results. Firstly, in the closed-economy case discussed in Ball (1999a), McCallum (1997), and Dennis (2001) stability or instability depends solely on the supply-side parameters, particularly on the slope of Phillips curve. In our open-economy case, however, stability relies on both supply-side and demand-side parameters because stability requires (1 2C ) A 1 while A contains both demand-side and supply-side parameters. Secondly, it is interesting to note that the model parameters in C are not directly responsible for stability since C is always less than 1 but greater than 0. By examining combined coefficient A and the stability conditions, we find that the model parameters that are directly responsible for stability are 1 and 1 , which determine, respectively, the effect of y t 1 on yt in the demand side and the effect of y t 1 on t in the supply side, because in the case of 0 1 1 and 0 1 1 stability for output and inflation is fully guaranteed3 no matter what the positive values all other model parameters take. Thirdly, since 0 C 1 implies (1 2C ) 3 , as the slope of the Phillips curve, 1 , becomes larger, the risk of instability increases for the given values of other 3 1 2 1 (1 1 )( 2 3 1 ) , so 0 1 1 and 0 1 1 together 2 3 1 2 1 0 A 1, but 0 A 1 is included in (1 2C ) A 1 as required since C is positive. Note that, since guarantee A 9 model parameters in A . Once 1 is large enough to cause A 3 , stability collapses under the nominal income targeting. The important policy implication is that the flatter the Phillips curve, the safer the policy of nominal income targeting in terms of stability. 5. Concluding Remarks In this paper, we have discussed the dynamic stability properties of the nominal income targeting rule in an open economy when both the stylized fact that the interest rate affects output before inflation and the formations of inflation expectations are taken into account. Some interesting results have been found and reported in the previous section. Although in theory monetary policy of nominal income targeting has attractive properties in terms of delivering better economic performance as measured by stability of output and inflation, this policy rule is indeed difficult to implement. For policy success, it is required that the monetary authority must know all these economic relations and behaviors correctly and must have accurate measures of macroeconomic variables, such as the output gap, in order to choose a right interest rate measure. If mistakes are made, a large efficiency loss in terms of more volatility of output and inflation may follow. These difficulties explain, to an extent, why no central banks have so far adopted monetary policy of nominal income targeting. However, this should not be used as the only factor to justify whether this policy rule is better or worse than others. The results of this study, therefore, suggest that while neither an absolutely positive nor absolutely negative judgment should be given to the policy rule of nominal 10 income targeting, a comprehensive study on economic relations and behaviors is required if implementation of such a monetary policy rule is in consideration. 11 References Ball, L., 1999a, Efficient rules for monetary policy, International Finance, 2, 63-83. ______, 1999b, Policy rules for open economies, in: J. B Taylor, eds., Monetary Policy Rules, The University of of Chicago Press, Chicago. Bean, C. R., 1983, Tageting nominal income: An appraisal, Economic Journal, 93, 806819. Bryant, R.C., P. Hooper, and C.L. Mann, 1993, Evaluating Policy Regimes: New Research in Empirical Macroeconomics, Brookings Institution, Washington DC. Dennis, R., 2001, Inflation expectations and the stability properties of nominal income targeting, The Economic Journal, 111, no. 468, 103-113. Feldstein, M.S. and J.H. Stock, 1994, The use of a monetary aggregate to target nominal GNP, in: N.G. Mankiw, eds., Monetary Policy, University of Chicago Press, Chicago. Fomby, T.B., R.C. Hill, and S.R. Johnson, 1984, Advanced Econometric Methods, Springer-Verlag, New York. Frankel, J and M. Chinn, 1995, The stabilizing properties of a nominal GNP rule, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 27, 319-334. Hall, R.E. and N.G. Mankiw, 1994, Nominal income targeting, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper, no. 4439. McCallum, B., 1983, On non-uniqueness in rational expectations models: an attempt at perspective, Journal of Monetary Economics, 11, 139-168. ____________ 1988, Robustness properties of a rule for monetary policy, CarnegieRochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 29, 173-204. _____________ 1990, Targets, indicators, and instruments of monetary policy, in: W.S. Haraf and P. Cagan, eds., Monetary Policy for a Changing Financial Environment, AEI Press, Washington DC. _____________ 1997, The alleged instability of nominal income targeting, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper, no. 6291. Ratti, R.A., 1997, The stabilizing properties of a nominal GNP rule: A comment, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 29, 263-269. Svensson, L., 1997, Inflation targeting: some extensions, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper, no. 5962. 12 Taylor, J. B., 1985, What would nominal income GNP targeting do to business cycle?, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 22, 61-84. __________ 1993, Discretion versus policy rules in practice, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 39, 195-214. Young, D. M., 1971, Iterative Solution of Large Linear Systems, Academic Press, New York. 13
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz