Import Competition and Multi Product Firms’ Productivity Richard Bräuer Matthias Mertens Viktor Slavtchev Abstract Both increasing market integration and declining productivity growth defined the European economic experience of the last decades. Against this background, we revisit the productivity effects of increasing foreign competition. In contrast to the previous literature, we take the heterogeneous effects predicted by theory into account. We find substantially different effect in line with endogenous growth models: Effects are more positive for technologically advanced competitors and the more important a product is to the firm. However, while competition from emerging countries favors productive firms, competition from industrialized countries leads to technology upgrading by previously unproductive firms. This is consistent with technology diffusion models. In contrast to previous studies, we also find negative productivity effects which stem from adjustment frictions: Firms cannot downsize as fast as necessary. Our estimates at the product level indicate that productivity increases due to new product launches, not improvements of existing ones. Both negative productivity and employment effects point towards substantial welfare losses for some participants in the economy. To arrive at these results, we propose adaptations to estimators for firm and firmproduct productivity. 1 Introduction Throughout the economic literature, fierce competition is credited with beneficial effects on partaking firms. This consensus has also been acted upon in a number of policy fields, ranging from competition policy to trade deals. However, it is grounded on a thoroughly static analysis. Recent models of endogenous investment in productivity or innovation view 1 competition much more ambiguously. This is because new entrants depress rents and thus returns on successful innovation. Conversely, they can also induce incumbents to escape competition through innovation (Aghion et al. 2004). We contribute to this discussion by measuring the causal effects of increased competition on firms’ productivity evolution. We indeed find both positive and negative effects, a first in the literature. We find that technologically advanced entrants cause relatively unproductive incumbents to increase their productivity and have an ambiguous effect on firm growth. This seems to indicate a technology transfer channel where laggards imitate innovative products and as a result do not suffer markedly. Contrarily, we find that entrance by technological laggards improves the efficiency of already productive incumbents but hurts relatively unproductive firms. Across the board, such entry causes substantial reductions in employment. To identify exogenous entrance and technology levels, we rely on imports from foreign countries and instrument them with productivity shocks to that country. We demonstrate that the declining productivity of some firms is caused by hysteresis: Firms losing market shares faster than they can cut back their input use, notably capital and labor. Thus, flexible input markets are necessary if an economy intends to capture the full productivity benefits, i.e. prevent productivity declines. This, however, comes at costs to workers outside the scope of our analysis: Workers suffer enduring losses when dismissed in general, a large part of which are picked up by state transfer programs (Fackler, Hank 2016). Their earnings also diminish when shrinking employment due to import competition forces them to switch sectors (Müller, Stegmaier, Yi 2016). In the aggregate, such shocks depress local labor markets, leading to persistent drag on employment (Autor, Dorn, Hansen 2013). Hence, there is convincing evidence that these costs can be severe. While there is no evidence of such hysteresis after competition shocks effects yet, there are several theoretical discussion of adjustment processes in general and their contribution to factor misallocation (Foster et al. 2016; Haltiwanger 2016). We also document asymmetric effects along different product lines within a firm. State of the art models of industrial competition and trade concern themselves with precisely these questions, too. Our results provide a much more nuanced picture of competition and can thus inform future modeling. In all of these ways, the paper thus contributes to our understanding of the microeconomic effects of competition in general and of international 2 integration in particular, about which our knowledge is still rather incomplete and fragmented (De Loecker, Goldberg 2014). To be able to analyze the evolution of efficiency, not market power, we propose and implement several improvements of the currently most commonly used TFPR estimators: We deflate output with a firm level price index, implement a price control function (De Loecker et al. 2016), estimate product level TFP (Dhyne et al. 2016) and propose a solution to the identification problem of TFP estimators analyzed by Gandhi et al. (2013). Fundamentally, the common estimators are not identified because intermediate inputs enter both as productivity proxy and production input. We propose a different productivity proxy constructed from all flexible inputs of the firm, which by construction differs from the intermediate inputs. This solves the identification problem without assuming a specific functional form or invoking the stronger assumptions of Gandhi et al. 2013. We also use our product level data to construct a much finer measure of import competition not at the industry, as is frequently done, but at the product and the firm level. This allows us to identify our effects within an industry, not between industries. With this, we contribute directly to the literature on endogenous firm innovation. Innovation is usually modeled in steps up a productivity/quality/technology ladder (see e.g. Grossman, Helpman 1999; Crepón, Duguet & Mairesse 1998; Aghion et al. 2004). Firms endogenously decide on whether to take up R&D in order to increase their chances of moving further up the ladder. Typically, in such models, firms innovate to stay ahead of their rivals while technology diffusion erodes their advantage. Because competition depresses potential monopoly rents earned through innovation, it also depresses R&D. On the other hand, too little competition would allow firms to reap monopoly rents even without continuously innovating to deter competition. Importantly, the effect of entrance in such a setup also relies on the technological ranking of entrants and incumbents: Too advanced new products make it implausible to overtake them and become technology leader, while too basic products do not threaten incumbents’ technologically grounded monopolies. Other types of models predict technology transfer as firms copy the designs of technologically advanced new products. We test these different models by distinguishing between high and low tech imports. Using quantile regression, we detect heterogeneous effects across the productivity distribution. 3 We find evidence for the imitation channel in the case of imports from industrialized products and support for ladder models in imports from middle income countries. This paper is also related to a growing body of empirical academic literature that investigates the effects of competition on firm level outcomes. Usually, using industry level productivity measures, the empirical literature finds significant positive effects of competition.1 Nevertheless, increases in foreign competition seem to have significant negative effects on local labor markets (see e.g. Autor, Dorn & Hanson 2016; Dauth, Findeisen, Suedekum 2014; Dauth, Findeisen, Suedekum 2016). Several studies have discussed the effects of trade liberalization in general on productivity. Note that this also includes new export opportunities for firms and that this usually accounts for the bulk of effects (e.g. Melitz, Treffler 2012). De Loecker (2011) gives a good overview over this literature and the difference between revenue and quantity productivity. He finds that in studies of this kind, price changes lead to dramatic overestimates of the productivity effects. We would also argue that competition increases inherently bias the evolution of revenue TFP: First, increased competition will depress prices, leading to a reduction in revenue. Second, trade has been shown to lower firm’s input prices, reducing costs and increasing mark-ups (De Loecker et al. 2016). Third, competition leads to redistribution of market shares from low to high mark-up firms and products (Melitz, Ottaviano 2008). De Loecker & Goldberg (2014) provide an overview of the identification challenges associated with this research set up. Compared to this literature, we offer both new findings and improvements of the methodology. Last, but not least, the literature puts a disproportionate emphasis on small open economies like Belgium (e.g. De Loecker et al. 2014; Dhyne et al., 2016). Thus, previous results may not be generalizable: Theory suggests that the measured effects are different for each combination of trading partners, depending on country characteristics (e.g. Melitz, Ottaviano 2008). To tackle such representation problems, we study Germany, a large industrialized economy. Such countries form a large part of the global economy, which makes our results transferable to a larger part of the global economy. Furthermore, we also conduct a comprehensive analysis of imports from several heterogeneous German trading partners and indeed find important differences in their effects. Our results thus provide a much clearer picture of the effects of market integration on productivity. The remainder of the paper is structured as follows: 1 See e.g. Holmes and Schmitz (2010) for a review of this literature. 4 Since our data has not yet been used in the related literature, Section two gives an overview over the data and our treatment of it. Section three describes our productivity estimation and discusses its assumptions, as well as advantages over the frequently used TFPR estimators. Section four presents and discusses our estimates of the effect of competition on productivity. Section five gives a summary of our results, details their implications and highlights areas of future research. 2 Data preparation and import competition measure Parts of the methodological advancements that we make are highly contingent on our data set. In the following, we will thus give an overview over our data sources and how representative they are, as well as over their scope and coverage. 2.1 The Comtrade Database To measure incoming import competition, we use data from the UN statistics division. The Comtrade database contains information on trade flows between countries. It theoretically represents the full universe of trade transactions. National statistical offices or other government sources form its basis, usually from customs data. For each product as classified by the Harmonized System or SITC, it contains the value of exports, imports, re-exports and re-imports for each combination of countries. Data quality varies according to who is actually providing the data, however, we take care to only use data provided by the most reliable reporters.2 Using classification provided by Eurostat, we reclassify these products into Europe’s PRODCOM classification. In ambiguous cases, we split the trade value proportionally the German market size for this product. 2.2 The German AfiD data For our analysis, we use the AfID-database gathered by Germany’s statistical offices, which so far has never been used for this kind of analysis. It is of higher quality than data sets typically used throughout the literature, both in reliability and in scope. Our data consists of two complementary panels, the product module and the firm module. Both span the full universe of German manufacturing firms for the years 1995-2014 with more than 20 employees. They contain information on revenue and quantity by product, wage bill, 2 Our analysis requires data reported from Germany, Great Britain, Norway, Sweden, Japan, New Zealand, Australia, Israel and Singapore. 5 investment and location for each plant of each firm. Firms are obliged to answer all questions by law. The negligible amount of missing values allows ruling out significant selection bias. However, to reduce the administrative burden for firms, some questions are only asked of a representative subsample of firms – e.g. firm level intermediate input use, research and exporting activities, the number of workers and non-industrial revenue. This unbalanced panel encompasses about 40% of revenue and employment of German manufacturing. Every four years, it is drawn anew. Because the sample is stratified according to industry and employment, which we observe for all variables, we can reweight this subsample to represent the whole population. With such detailed information on products, cost structure and research & exporting activities, we can take a closer look at firms than is usually possible. 2.3 Reclassification of products One of the key advantages of the AFiD data is the availability of revenue and quantity data on the product level. We use this data to assign industry codes and import competition to each firm. Products are classified in the German GP schematic, the first eight digits being equivalent to the European system PRODCOM. A ninth digit allows for an even finer categorization of products. The tenth digit shows whether the produce is sold or produced on commission. About 3500 different eight-digit product codes are found in the data each year. PRODCOM and thus GP changed several times during the 20 years in consideration. For comparability, we transform all codes both into the GP 2002 and the GP 2009. To do this, we use the concordances provided by the German statistical offices, which are usually unambiguous. In case of ambiguity, we compare the product portfolios before and after the changes and settle on the only code that can also be found after the change. If this leaves us with multiple or no options, we do not make additional assumptions and do not switch the code. In most such cases, we are still able to assign the first few digits of the classification unambiguously, which we exploit for the reclassification of industries (see 2.4). All in all, the problem of changing classifications is negligible: We are able to construct consistent ten digit product codes for about 96% of all products in question. When looking at the first few digits, the problem disappears entirely: We were able to assign the first four digits of the product code in 99.5% of all cases (99.9% for the first two digits). 6 2.4 Reclassification of industries In 2002 and even more fundamentally in 2009, the European industry definitions were reworked. Thus, new and old industry codes are generally considered to be incomparable due to these dramatic changes in the underlying classification. However, in order to estimate a production function for each industry and to merge industry level deflators for inputs, we need a time consistent industry classification. We circumvent this problem by inferring the firm specific industry code from the product data. This exploits the fact that the first four digits of a PRODCOM code equal the industry which produces the product. When assigning the industry classification to a firm, we closely follow the general methodology of the German statistical office for picking the industry code most representative of a firm’s product portfolio.3 The codes frequently used throughout the literature tend to be selfreported by the firms. Frequently, there is an unenforceable recommendation to pick the industry with the most workers or value added. To the contrary, our self-constructed measure determines the center of gravity of production in terms of revenue, arguably more appropriate for a revenue-based production function. In any case, we arrive at very similar results: 4% of firms provide a different code than the one we assign. In rare cases, a firm had revenue in a product we could not assign to our time consistent industries. If this product was important enough to potentially change the industry assigned, we did not assign any industry. However, such cases were negligible. We use these time consistent industry codes (which follow NACE Rev1.1) to estimate separate production functions for each industry. We merge price indices for production, depreciations, intermediate inputs and various capital goods prices by two digit industry sector. 2.5 Firm Level Price Indices In productivity analysis, it is generally acknowledged that price movements confound the estimates: If researchers only have access to revenue data and industry specific output deflators, they cannot distinguish between price increases and additional production within 3 First, we consider the two digit industry of the firm: Here, we pick the one that combines the most product revenue. Second, with this two digit industry, we determine the three digit industry that contains most product revenue. Third, within this smaller industry, we define the 4 digit code with most production. This is basically done by defining that the main activity of a firm lies in the industry in which it produces most of its revenue. 7 firms of the same industry.4 Thus, both will lead to higher productivity estimates. However, we are able to eliminate this source of bias by using firm-product level data: Following Eslava et al. (2004), we construct a Törnqvist price index for firms. This index is computed as 𝑛 1 (𝑠𝑖𝑔𝑡 +𝑠𝑖𝑔𝑡−1 ) 𝑝𝑖𝑔𝑡 2 𝑃𝑖𝑡 = ∏ ( ) 𝑝𝑖𝑔𝑡−1 𝑃𝑖𝑡−1 , 𝑔=1 where 𝑝𝑖𝑔𝑡 is the price of good 𝑔 and 𝑠𝑖𝑔𝑡 is the corresponding share of this good in the production at firm 𝑖 in period 𝑡. Thus, the growth of the index value is the product of the individual products’ price growths, each weighted with the average revenue share of that product over this year and the last. For our start year we set 𝑃𝑖𝑡=2001 = 100. For firms entering after the start year we use an industry average as starting price index. This methodology has the advantage that new products slip into the index calculation seamlessly: In this case, 𝑠𝑖𝑔𝑡−1 = 0, 𝑠𝑖𝑔𝑡 ≠ 0. In fact, the weights of the index are adjusted every year. When computing the average price growth like proposed by Laspeyres, new products have zero weight. Thus, practitioners have to change the underlying basket of goods manually. This forces them to make many arbitrary decisions, because firms’ product portfolios change relatively fast. We use this price index to deflate industrial revenue. However, we do not have a single firm in our sample with zero revenue outside of manufacturing. Firms also sell services like transportation, produce capital goods (for own use mostly), sell products from their warehouses, etc. The assertion that product prices move in tandem with prices for these activities seem dubious, so we deflate each of them with the best deflators available from the statistical offices.5 We want to emphasize that our data also represents the full data basis for constructing the official industry 2-digit deflator supplied by the statistical office of Germany, which regularly 4 Thus, a 5% increase in prices and a 5% increase in output would create the same observation for estimation. When estimated, the result is often called TFPR, or revenue TFP. This contains improvements in production technology and changes in market power. For most analyses, this creates severe measurement problems. Needless to say, prices within the 27 broad industries that form the manufacturing sector do not move in perfect synchrony. 5 Specifically, we use the capital goods deflator for self-produced capital goods, we use the BIP deflator for the very diverse category of service revenue and we use firms’ manufacturing goods price deflator for revenue from warehouse sales. Main results are robust to different treatments of non industrial revenue. 8 is used to estimate revenue based productivity (TFPR). However, TFPR captures undesired price fluctuations between firms within the same industries, which may lead to serious mismeasurement of true firm level productivity effects. Especially when considering the effect of import competition, there is ample evidence that markups may rise due to lower intermediate input prices (see De Loecker et al. 2016, De Loecker 2011), which would wrongly be considered as true efficiency gains when estimating productivity as TFPR instead of TFPQ. Using a firm level price index, like we described, will lead to a TFPQ measure of productivity which measures TFP in quantity instead of revenue terms, as this price index purges the output variable form all price variation. Importantly, when constructing our price index, we do not make any additional assumptions, compared to using the industry deflator supplied by the statistical office and therefore also compared to other studies that use TFPR as their productivity measure. This is essentially true because we use exactly the same data base as the statistical office when it creates its industry deflator. In a sense, the only thing we do different compared to the statistical office is that we aggregate product level prices to a lower level, i.e. the firm level. Therefore, in any case, our firm specific price index is superior compared to using an industry deflator when one wants to make statements about the evolution of true technological efficiency. 3 Methodology: Estimating TFP and import competition This section explains our empirical strategy for estimating the effect of import competition on firm- and firm-product-level TFP. Chapter 3.1 starts with describing our framework for estimating a production function at the firm level. Importantly, we will take care of the fact that firms are multi-product firms by deflating revenue-based output with a self-created firm specific price deflator. Section 3.2 then shows the methodology for estimating TFP at the firm-product-level. Section 3.3 and 3.4 follow with explaining the construction of our import competition measure. 9 3.1 Estimating a firm-level production function for multi-product firms 3.1.1 Setting and general notes To illustrate our approach we start with a standard Cobb-Douglas firm-level production function in logs: 𝑞𝑖𝑡 = 𝛽𝑙 𝑙𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑘 𝑘𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑚 𝑚𝑖𝑡 + 𝜔𝑖𝑡 + 𝜀𝑖𝑡 , (1) where 𝑞𝑖𝑡 is the log of properly deflated revenue from all firm activities. 𝑙𝑖𝑡 is the log of full time equivalents used by the firm, our preferred measure of labor input. 𝑚𝑖𝑡 represents the log of intermediate inputs, 𝑘𝑖𝑡 symbolizes the log of the capital stock6, 𝜔𝑖𝑡 is the productivity shock, 𝜀𝑡 is an i.i.d. disturbance term that is per assumption uncorrelated with all inputs, and 𝛽𝑙 , 𝛽𝑘 , 𝛽𝑚 are the output elasticities of the production function. The indices 𝑖 and 𝑡 symbolize the firm and time dimension respectively.7 Note that in order to arrive at a consistent estimate of 𝜔𝑖𝑡 the production variables above should represent all inputs used and outputs produced. E.g. consider a case where due to data availability, service revenues are excluded from 𝑞𝑖𝑡 , which is not uncommon in the literature. In this case, a firm which uses a lot of its inputs to produce service revenue would receive a much lower TFP than is actually warranted. Since this is an endogenous choice made by the firm (e.g. large firms might find it optimal to provide relatively more services), this introduces not only measurement error but systematic bias. This also means one cannot simply leave out a part of the inputs and assume that both problems “cancels each other out”.8 However, assuming all of the above variables are well defined, the equation is still not identified econometrically. This is because the firm potentially observes its own productivity 𝜔𝑖𝑡 and choses its inputs accordingly. Hence, simple OLS suffers from an omitted variable 6 See Appendix A for the construction of the capital variable. When choosing which cost categories to include in which input variable, we remained consistent with the definition of the statistical offices. This consistency allows us to aggregate firm level results to the country level. 8 E.g. intermediate inputs are often only defined as raw materials, while outputs may be defined as the sum of the product based production value. This would only then be correct if the ignored inputs were only used for the production of the ignore output, an unlikely hypothesis. 7 10 and we cannot back out productivity as the residuum of this estimation. In the following we will detail our solution to this problem. 3.1.2 Identification strategy Our empirical strategy for estimating a production function at the firm level is based on the well known framework of Olley, Pakes (1996) and Levinsohn, Petrin (2003), which was repeatedly modified and improved by other scholars of this field. Our version of this approach is best described as an extension of the popular Wooldridge-LP approach (Wooldridge 2009; Petrin, Levinsohn 2012). For an overview of these techniques, see e.g. Ornaghi and Van Beveren (2012). First, we augment this backbone by incorporating the treatment of input price bias described in De Loecker et al. (2016). Second, we make use of our high quality data to implement a simple but effective way to deal with the criticism of Gandhi et al. (2013) regarding the identification problem of the intermediate input coefficient in gross output based production functions. As it is standard in the literature, we assume that 𝜔 is a state variable unobserved by the econometrician but observed by the firm and described by a first-order Markov process, i.e. follows the law of motion: 𝜔𝑖𝑡 = ℎ(𝜔𝑖𝑡−1 ) + 𝜉𝑖𝑡 , with 𝜉𝑖𝑡 being the innovation in productivity. We assume that intermediate inputs are freely adjustable, i.e. that firms choose their intermediate input consumption only after observing the productivity shock. 9 Contrary, Capital and Labor are assumed to be “quasi-fixed variables” and to be determined before the shock. Therefore 𝑙𝑖𝑡 and 𝑘𝑖𝑡 are part of the state variable space of the firm. Treating 𝑙𝑖𝑡 as quasi-fixed input seems to be a reasonable assumption for the German labor market.10 Thus, both 𝑙𝑖𝑡 and 𝑘𝑖𝑡 are assumed to be correlated with past productivity ℎ(𝜔𝑖𝑡−1 ), but uncorrelated with the productivity innovation 𝜉𝑖𝑡 . As argued in the literature, this allows to identify all parameters using a control function: The firm’s choice of intermediate inputs can be described by a function of productivity and all state variables describing the decision problem of the firm 𝑚𝑡 = ℎ𝑡 (𝜔𝑖𝑡 , 𝑘𝑖𝑡 , 𝑙𝑖𝑡 , 𝑧𝑖𝑡 ). Ornaghi and Van Beveren (2012) showed that ℎ𝑡 is a monotone function. In this case, we can 9 To be exact, it is sufficient to assume that some parts of 𝑚𝑖𝑡 are flexible. E.g. raw materials and energy are flexible, while intermediate services are quasi-fixed. 10 The OECD indicators of employment protection (OECD, 2013) show that the labor market regulations in Germany are relatively strict compared to other countries. Therefore treating 𝑙𝑖𝑡 as fixed input seems justifiable, especially when considering the fact that agency workers are part of the intermediate input variable. 11 rearrange it to obtain: 𝜔𝑖𝑡 = 𝑔(𝑘𝑖𝑡 , 𝑙𝑖𝑡 , 𝒛𝑖𝑡 , 𝑚𝑖𝑡 ). Substituting this and the law of motion of productivity into the original equation, we arrive at 𝑞𝑖𝑡 = 𝛽𝑙 𝑙𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑘 𝑘𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑚 𝑚𝑖𝑡 + 𝑔(𝑘𝑖𝑡−1 , 𝑙𝑖𝑡−1 , 𝒛𝑖𝑡−1 , 𝑚𝑖𝑡−1 ) + 𝜉𝑖𝑡 + 𝜀𝑖𝑡 The vector 𝒛𝑖𝑡−1 should provide a description of the decision making problem of the firm. It should thus be as broad as possible (De Loecker and Warzynski (2012)). Here we utilize the number of variables in our data set and incorporate export status, research activities, location of firm headquarters, industry dummies and the number of products. The results are robust to different operationalization of these variables, as well as to different approximations of the functional form of 𝑔𝑡 . All flexible variables are instrumented with their own lags. The problem raised by Gandhi et al. (2013) is that using 𝑚 simultaneously as proxy for 𝜔𝑖𝑡 and as an argument in the production function gives rise to another identification problem: Since 𝑚𝑖𝑡 must be flexible in order to serve as a proxy, it has to be instrumented with its lag. However, in the above setting, 𝑚𝑖𝑡 lacks any exogenous variation that could be recovered via this instrument. To see this, insert the control function into the law of motion of productivity. This gives: 𝑚𝑖𝑡 = ℎ𝑡 (𝜔𝑖𝑡 , 𝑘𝑖𝑡 , 𝑙𝑖𝑡 , 𝑧𝑖𝑡 ) = ℎ𝑡 (𝑔(𝑚𝑖𝑡−1 , 𝑘𝑖𝑡−1 , 𝑙𝑖𝑡−1 , 𝒛𝑖𝑡−1 ) + 𝜉𝑖𝑡 , 𝑘𝑖𝑡 , 𝑙𝑖𝑡 , 𝑧𝑖𝑡 ) This shows that 𝑚𝑖𝑡 is determined by a function of its own lag, contemporaneous and past values of the state variables, and a random disturbance 𝜉𝑖𝑡 that is by assumption uncorrelated with anything. Therefore 𝑚𝑖𝑡 lacks any exogenous variation after conditioning on the arguments of ℎ𝑡 .11 However, this problem can be circumvented by postulating a slightly different reaction of the firms to its state variables. Notice that 𝑚𝑖𝑡 is not a term actually observed, but rather an aggregate of very different inputs: It contains the services of the firms cleaning the office buildings as well as raw material input. While the firm probably choses the later in response to TFP fluctuations, this is probably not true for other components. Since the firm’s flexible 11 We refer the interested reader to Gandhi et al. (2013) for an illuminating discussion on the identification problem associated with flexible inputs. 12 adjustment of the control variable in response to productivity shocks is the backbone of the methodology, one should only include really flexible inputs into the control function. Examples include energy or raw material usage, use of interim staffing and perhaps investment variables. All of these individual items have the advantage of not being part of the production function, so there is no need for instruments and no identification problem. Any firm level data set should include at least some of the above variables, so this approach is open to other researchers working with different data. For this application, we stick with raw materials plus energy usage, 𝑒𝑖𝑡 , because of their familiarity from other uses in firm level data. However, we found that the results are robust to different definitions of the proxy. Having dealt with the identification problem inherent to the standard approach, we could proceed to estimate the equation if all of our above variables were observed in real terms. However, while we can built an exact deflator for output, we do not observe input prices. The seminal paper by De Loecker et al. (2016) shows how to deal with this problem common to virtually all firm level data sets. However, such quantity data is typically not available, and furthermore, even if such a dataset would exist, one would have to conduct an aggregation of many different inputs and many different outputs of a firm into a few variables, that allow formulating a (meaningful) production function. Therefore, the standard approach in the existing literature is to use the best possible deflator, i.e. the most disaggregated, to deflate nominal values of inputs and outputs into quasi-quantities.12 Normally researchers therefore use industry level deflators. For our dataset we are, however, able to improve on this practice by constructing a firmspecific output price index from the available information on product quantities and prices. Regarding the input side, we do not have to deflate the labor input as it is reported in quantities, while intermediate inputs and capital are deflated by a 2-digit-industry deflator supplied by the statistical office of Germany. De Loecker et al. (2016) show how using industry-deflators for inputs creates a price-bias when estimating a production function like the one in (1).13 We follow their solution to this 12 They are obviously not real quantities, because the price deflator is not equal to the price. Deflating inputs or outputs with a deflator, normalized in year 𝑡 implicitly assumes that the price differences between the inputs or outputs of the firms in year 𝑡 stay constant, which could for example be interpreted as assuming that quality differences between products in year 𝑡 are constant over time, i.e. last forever. 13 The underlying reason is that firms producing the same good(s) may have different prices, e.g. due to quality differences of their products. Industry price deflators ignore these differences within industries. Not controlling 13 problem, assume a vertical differentiation model of demand, and include the output price of ∗ a firm, 𝑝𝑖𝑡 , as separate price control function. This demand structure implies that output prices will be perfect proxies for input prices. In order to make the output price comparable ∗ between firms within the same 2-digit-industry, we define the price of a firm product, 𝑝𝑖𝑔𝑡 , for every good 𝑔 as the deviation from the average product price. For the firm-level equation, we then sum up all products inside a firm using revenue share weights. ∗ Implementing 𝑝𝑖𝑡 and the control function approach detailed above leads to: ∗ 𝑞𝑖𝑡 = 𝛽𝑙 𝑙𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑘 𝑘𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑚 𝑚𝑖𝑡 + 𝛾𝑝𝑖𝑔𝑡 + 𝑔(𝑒𝑖𝑡−1 , 𝑘𝑖𝑡−1 , 𝑙𝑖𝑡−1 , 𝒛𝑖𝑡−1 ) + 𝜉𝑖𝑡 + 𝜀𝑖𝑡 . (5) To translate this equation into an estimation, we use the following moment conditions, which come from our assumptions about the two stochastic error processes: 𝑙𝑖𝑡 𝑘𝑖𝑡 𝑚𝑖𝑡−1 ∗ 𝑝𝑖𝑡−1 𝐸 (𝜉𝑖𝑡 + 𝜀𝑖𝑡 ) 𝑒𝑖𝑡−1 =0 , 𝑙𝑖𝑡−1 𝑘𝑖𝑡−1 𝐳𝑖𝑡−1 [ ( 𝚪𝑖𝑡−1 ) ] (6) where 𝚪𝒊𝑡−1 colletcts higher order interaction terms of 𝑔(. ). We proceed to estimate this with a simple moment estimator, following the standard procedure of Wooldridge (2009) and Petrin, Levinsohn (2012).14 This means that we ∗ instrument 𝑚𝑖𝑡 and 𝑝𝑖𝑡 with their lagged values while all static variables are exogenous to current TFP and thus serve as their own instruments. After having consistent estimates for the production function we can calculate productivity: ∗ 𝜔𝑖𝑡 = 𝑞𝑖𝑡 − (𝛽𝑙 𝑙𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑘 𝑘𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑚 𝑚𝑖𝑡 + 𝛾𝑝𝑖𝑡 ) (7) With this estimate, we have a state of the art productivity measure including input price controls, circumventing the identification problems of the standard approach. This is thus arguably a consistent estimate of the real productivity of firms, which is often called TFPQ. for these price differences then obviously generates biases in the input coefficients. We refer the reader to De Loecker et al. (2016) for further details. 14 To absorb the high dimensional dummies we use the command reghdfe by Correia (2015). 14 3.2 Estimating a firm-product level production function For estimating a firm-product level production function we follow the novel framework by Dhyne et al. (2016) and shortly note that their approach is generalizable to single product firms if one uses more than production based outputs for the output variable definition (as we propose). The core idea of Dhyne et al. (2016) is based on work of Diewert (1972) and Lau (1976). Dhyne et al. (2016) show that it is possible to formulate a firm-product level production function which can be used to estimate productivity of single products of a multi-product firm. We do not rewrite their derivations and instead recommend their working paper for further elaborations. Again, we draw from the insights of De Loecker et al. (2016) and ∗ include a product level price control function, constituted from the product price, 𝑝𝑖𝑔𝑡 , and ∗ product market share, 𝑚𝑠𝑖𝑔𝑡 , into the estimation to purge our productivity measure from undesirable input price variation between firms and products (we want to recover a pure ∗ ∗ quantity measure of productivity).15 We define the price control function as 𝜑(𝑝𝑖𝑔𝑡 , 𝑚𝑠𝑖𝑔𝑡 ) and write our estimation equation as: ∗ ∗ 𝑞𝑖𝑔𝑡 = 𝛽𝑙 𝑙𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑘 𝑘𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑚 𝑚𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽−𝑔 𝑟𝑖(−𝑔)𝑡 + 𝜑(𝑝𝑖𝑔𝑡 , 𝑚𝑠𝑖𝑔𝑡 ) + 𝜔𝑖𝑡𝑔 + 𝜀𝑖𝑔𝑡 , (8) where 𝑔 is an index for variables referring to product 𝑔. It follows that 𝑞𝑖𝑔𝑡 is the log quantity of good 𝑔, while 𝑟𝑖(−𝑔)𝑡 symbolizes the log of all other revenue of a firm 𝑖 at time 𝑡 and is deflated with an index which heeds the exclusion of product 𝑔 from 𝑟𝑖(−𝑔)𝑡 . Equation (8) needs some discussion. First note that the input coefficients 𝑙𝑖𝑡 , 𝑘𝑖𝑡 , and 𝑚𝑖𝑡 are firm level variables. This means that the approach by Dhyne et al. (2016) requires that after including a control variable for all revenue but the revenue of good 𝑔 one can recover a productivity estimate for good 𝑔. In this sense the individual input coefficients have to be interpreted as the percentage change of output 𝑔 after increasing the specific input by one percent, conditional on all other inputs and all other revenue sources being constant. Second, as Dhyne et al. (2016) show, equation (8) is only correctly specified when 𝛽−𝑔 < 0 15 At the firm level estimation we could not simply implement a market share variable because firms are simultaneously engaged in very different markets. We also omitted the product market share from the product level estimation which leads to very similar results. 15 and 𝛽𝑥 > 0 with 𝑥 = (𝑙, 𝑘, 𝑚) holds. The returns to scale for product 𝑔 are somewhat difficult to interpret in the presence of coefficient 𝛽−𝑔 . One has to consider all 𝛽-coefficients simultaneously. Third, we want to mention that equation (8) is only a general production function when a firm produces at least two outputs. This means that neglecting the output sources besides the product production output will lead to an exclusion of single products firm when estimating equation (8), because log( 𝑟𝑖(−𝑔)𝑡 ) = log( 0) will be not defined. Like before, we use all revenue sources a firm generates in period 𝑡 (i.e. abstracting from inaccuracies of deflating, in our case it theoretically holds that exp(𝑞𝑖𝑔𝑡 ) + exp(𝑟𝑖(−𝑔)𝑡 ) = exp(𝑞𝑖𝑡 ) ). This ensures that equation (8) is defined for single and multi-product firms. The steps of recovering a product level productivity estimate from equation (8) are basically identical to the firm level framework discussed in chapter 3.1. The only differences are that ∗ we now also have to instrument 𝑟𝑖(−𝑔)𝑡 with its first lag and that the vector 𝐳𝑖𝑔𝑡 now includes product level control variables.16 For completeness we rewrite (8) as: 𝑞𝑖𝑔𝑡 = 𝛽𝑙 𝑙𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑘 𝑘𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑚 𝑚𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽−𝑔 𝑟𝑖(−𝑔)𝑡 ∗ ∗ ∗ + 𝜑(𝑝𝑖𝑔𝑡 , 𝑚𝑠𝑖𝑔𝑡 ) + 𝑔(𝑒𝑖𝑡−1 , 𝑘𝑖𝑡−1 , 𝑙𝑖𝑡−1 , 𝐳𝑖𝑔𝑡−1 ) + 𝜀𝑖𝑔𝑡 + 𝜉𝑖𝑔𝑡 , (9) which is identified by the moment conditions: 𝑙𝑖𝑡 𝑘𝑖𝑡 𝑚𝑖𝑡−1 ∗ 𝑝𝑖𝑔𝑡−1 ∗ 𝑚𝑠𝑖𝑔𝑡−1 𝑒𝑖𝑡−1 𝐸 (𝜉𝑖𝑔𝑡 + 𝜀𝑖𝑔𝑡 ) = 0. 𝑙𝑖𝑡−1 𝑘𝑖𝑡−1 ∗ 𝐳𝑖𝑔𝑡−1 𝚪𝑖𝑡−1 [ (𝑟𝑖(−𝑔)𝑡−1 ) ] (10) 16 We include the rank of the product within the firm (in terms of revenue shares), product dummies and location dummies of the firms headquarter. 16 After having consistent estimates for the input coefficients, firm-product level productivity can be calculated: ∗ ∗ 𝜔𝑖𝑔𝑡 = 𝑞𝑖𝑔𝑡 − (𝛽𝑙 𝑙𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑘 𝑘𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑚 𝑚𝑖𝑡 + 𝜑(𝑝𝑖𝑔𝑡 , 𝑚𝑠𝑖𝑔𝑡 ) + 𝛽−𝑔 𝑟𝑖(−𝑔)𝑡 ). (11) When using equation (9) we follow the advice of Dhyne et al. (2016) and only consider the products that represent at least 5% of a firms’ revenue. 3.3 Trade data and import competition measure In this chapter, we lay out a methodology to deal with two recurrent problems in the literature. First, previous studies on import competition have often suffered from an imprecise measurement of competition, usually utilizing firms’ industry branches. All firms within an industry thus had the same import competition by assumption. Apart from this being imprecise, it forced researchers to compare firms in different industries with each other to gauge the effect of competition. Second, import shocks from individual countries are often considered independently. However, it is very likely that they are correlated: E.g. trade negotiations that lead to WTO ascendancies are linked via the diplomatic and political climate around trade negotiations in general. Therefore, we consider import shocks from most German trading partners jointly. We further sort countries in terms of their GDP per capita into high income and low income countries. This separation functions as a proxy for high and low wage countries and aims at investigating potential differences in the effects of import competition on productivity for each country group.17 We are able to assemble such a precise and comprehensive data set by using the UN Comtrade database in the Harmonized System (version of 2002) and relate it to the PRODCOM 8-digit classification of 2002. Whenever this concordance is ambiguous, we split the import volume according to the domestic production of the ambiguous goods. This allows us to compute both total production and total import exposure on the level of 17 Our high income country group encompasses USA, Canada, Japan, and South Korea, while our middle-low income country group is constituted of China, India, Russia, Brazil, South Africa, Argentina, Chile, Mexico, Malaysia, Turkey, Thailand, Tunisia, Bangladesh, Indonesia, Philippines, Vietnam, and Pakistan. Note that we consider only countries that contribute at least 0.001% to the total imports in the manufacturing sector of Germany and that are not directly linked to Germany via common currency or geographical neighborhood. 17 individual products. Following the work of Dhyne et al. (2016) and Dauth et al. (2014) we compute our measure of import competition, the import share as 𝑛→𝐺𝑒𝑟𝑚𝑎𝑛𝑦 𝑀𝑔𝑡 𝑛 𝐼𝑆𝑔𝑡 𝑛→𝐺𝑒𝑟𝑚𝑎𝑛𝑦 = 𝑀𝑔𝑡 𝑀𝑔𝑡 +𝑌𝑔𝑡 ∗ 100. denotes the imports of good 𝑔 from country (-group) 𝑛 to Germany, 𝑀𝑔𝑡 denotes all imports of good 𝑔 into Germany and 𝑌𝑔𝑡 equals total production within Germany. As evident from the index 𝑛, we can compute this for all trading partners of Germany. We compute the import exposure of the individual firm as the revenue-weighted average pressures across its’ product portfolio. This allows for the fact that even within an industry, firms face different import competition, based on their product portfolio. 3.4 Instrument and Identification While computable for every product and trading partner, the import competition itself is probably endogenous. We use an instrument similar in spirit to Autor, Dorn & Hanson 2013, which has already been used in the context of Germany by Dauth, Findeisen & Suedekum 2016: Fluctuations in the exogenous competitiveness of the foreign country. An example would be Chinese firms picking up semiconductor manufacture or becoming much better in it as a result of internal Chinese productivity developments. This constitutes an exogenous rise in competition from the viewpoint of German firms producing semiconductors. We measure this exogenous competition by looking at third markets: If China is capturing a big share of the import markets of other countries, we conclude that its competitiveness has indeed risen. Specifically, we look at China’s market share among imported goods in a set of control countries. We take countries whose markets for industrial products we consider roughly comparable to Germany, but which are not directly related to Germany via common currency or geographical neighborhood.18 We compute our instrument for each product as 𝑛 𝐼𝑁𝑆𝑔𝑡 = 𝑛→𝐼𝑁𝑆 𝑀𝑔𝑡 𝐼𝑁𝑆 𝑀𝑔𝑡 𝑛→𝐼𝑁𝑆 ∗ 100 . 𝑀𝑔𝑡 stands for imports from the country (-group) of interest into 𝐼𝑁𝑆 any of the instrument countries, while 𝑀𝑔𝑡 is just total imports into these countries. One can describe it as the market share of e.g. China in the joint import market of the instrument countries. Again, to arrive at a measure for each firm, we aggregate over all 𝐼𝑁𝑆𝑔𝑡 , weighted with firm specific revenue weights. For the estimation we aggregate over all instruments, leading to one instrument per endogenous import competition shock. 18 This list currently entails Norway, New Zealand, Israel, Australia, Great Britain, Sweden, and Singapore. Various robustness checks have shown that the results are not altered greatly by choosing a different list. 18 4 Empirical Results This Chapter presents our estimation results as well as some descriptive statistics regarding the evolution our measures of import competition and productivity. In section 4.1 we present the results from our firm level and firm-product level production function estimation. Both production functions are estimated at the NACE rev. 1.1 2-digit-level in order to allow the coefficients of the production functions to vary between industries. In section 4.2 we present results from our regression of firm and firm-product level productivity on import competition. We find that qualitatively and quantitatively the effects of import competition on productivity depend on the country of origin and that productivity effects are partly disguised at the firm level due to an asymmetric effect of import competition over the product portfolios of firms. We emphasize the importance of product market analyses to measure the impact of import competition on domestic productivity. 4.1 Production function estimates Table 1 presents the output elasticities for capital, labor, and intermediate inputs from estimating the firm level equation (5) for every NACE rev. 1.1 2-digit-industry for which we have more than 500 observations. 19 Table 1 Output elasticities from estimating equation (5) for every nace rev. 1.1 2-digit-industry with more than 500 observations Labor Capital Intermediate Returns to inputs scale Sector 15 (Food products and beverages) 17 (Textiles) 18 (Wearing apparel; dressing and dyeing of fur) 19 (Leather and leather products) 20 (Wood and wood products) 21 (Pulp, paper, and paper products) 24 (Chemicals and chemical products) 25 (Rubber and plastic products) 26 (Other non-metallic mineral products) 27 (Basic metals) Number of observations (1) 0.14 (0.03) 0.31 (0.05) 0.14 (0.07) (2) 0.23 (0.07) 0.14 (0.1) 0.27 (0.14) (3) 0.75 (0.02) 0.73 (0.04) 0.81 (0.03) (4) 1.13 (5) 9913 1.18 2622 1.22 650 0.30 (0.07) 0.04 (0.10) 0.76 (0.04) 1.1 0.20 (0.06) 0.17 (0.05) 0.29 (0.05) 0.18 (0.04) 0.18 (0.05) 0.22 (0.05) 0.06 (0.06) 0.06 (0.04) 0.05 (0.06) 0.06 (0.05) -0.05 (0.04) 0.01 (0.04) 0.76 (0.03) 0.8 (0.03) 0.77 (0.03) 0.71 (0.03) 0.74 (0.02) 0.76 (0.03) 1.02 1627 1.02 2248 1.11 4407 0.95 4874 0.87 4547 0.99 3907 -0.01 (0.04) 0.68 (0.02) 0.88 7207 0.09 (0.06) 0.16 (0.08) 0.11 (0.13) 0.06 (0.09) 0.02 (0.08) 0.11 (0.06) 0.77 (0.05) 0.60 (0.04) 0.79 (0.05) 0.66 (0.04) 0.75 (0.04) 0.74 (0.03) 1.05 4136 1.1 2623 1.14 695 1.02 1539 0.86 1081 1.11 2396 28 (Fabricated metal 0.21 products, except machinery, (0.04) and equipment) 29 (Machinery and 0.18 Equipment n.e.c.) (0.06) 31 (Electrical machinery and 0.33 apparatus n.e.c.) (0.06) 32 (Radio, television, and 0.24 communication) (0.13) 33 (Medical, precision, and 0.31 optical instruments) (0.09) 34 (Motor vehicles, trailers 0.09 and semi-trailers) (0.08) 36 (Furniture; manufacturing 0.25 n.e.c.) (0.07) Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 515 Our coefficients are in line with our expectations, although we find relatively high standard errors for the capital coefficients. This is not surprising as using firm specific price indices forces us to reduce our sample noticeably. Further, firms within a broadly defined 2-digit industry are still characterized by a high degree of heterogeneity. Due to using firm specific output price indices while simultaneously controlling for input prices, we relate output quantities to input quantities. Compared to using industry deflators (a revenue based 20 concept) this should amplify the variation in the output elasticities as firms, even in the same 2-digit industry, produce very different outputs. For this reason, we would ideally like to estimate a production function for each firm separately, which, however, is impossible due to the known data limitations. Evidently from table 1, output elasticities with respect to production inputs vary enormously between industries, which is in line with the theory and emphasizes the importance of allowing different production functions for separate industries. When calculating productivity according to equation (7) we drop industries for which we computed negative output elasticities with respect to capital, labor, or intermediate inputs. We do this because the production function itself is not well defined in those cases. Table 2 presents our estimates for our firm-product level production function, which is represented by equation (9). This takes the whole productivity estimation one step further and allows for heterogeneous productivity levels among products within the same firm. 21 Table 2 Output elasticities from estimating equation (9) for every nace rev. 1.1 2-digit-product with more than 500 observations Labor Capital Intermediate Other inputs revenue Sector 15 (Food products and beverages) 17 (Textiles) 18 (Wearing apparel; dressing and dyeing of fur) 19 (Leather and leather products) 20 (Wood and wood products) 21 (Pulp, paper, and paper products) 23 (Coke, refined petroleum products and nuclear fuel) 24 (Chemicals and chemical products) 25 (Rubber and plastic products) 26 (Other non-metallic mineral products) 27 (Basic metals) 28 (Fabricated metal products, except machinery, and equipment) 29 (Machinery and Equipment n.e.c.) 31 (Electrical machinery and apparatus n.e.c.) 32 (Radio, television, and communication) 33 (Medical, precision, and optical instruments) 34 (Motor vehicles, trailers and semi-trailers) 36 (Furniture; manufacturing n.e.c.) (1) 0.09 (0.07) 0.82 (0.16) 1.08 (0.45) 1.26 (0.49) 0.57 (0.14) 0.47 (0.10) 0.54 (0.35) 0.4 (0.09) 0.4 (0.07) 0.44 (0.14) 0.43 (0.09) (2) 0.21 (0.12) 0.23 (0.2) -0.78 (0.91) 0.41 (0.49) 0.06 (0.13) 0.18 (0.09) 0.06 (0.16) -0.12 (0.16) 0.09 (0.08) 0.51 (0.16) 0.07 (0.11) (3) 0.76 (0.85) 0.41 (0.14) 0.32 (0.31) 0.52 (0.25) 0.65 (0.12) 0.4 (0.08) 0.36 (0.17) 0.72 (0.08) 0.6 (0.06) 0.77 (0.09) 0.72 (0.08) (4) -0.43 (0.04) -0.36 (0.04) -0.9 (0.18) -0.43 (0.09) -0.33 (0.04) -0.22 (0.02) -0.56 (0.12) -0.31 (0.03) -0.30 (0.01) -0.34 (0.06) -0.33 (0.02) 0.52 (0.09) 0.41 (0.15) 0.48 (0.10) 0.52 (0.3) 0.29 (0.17) 0.66 (0.18) 0.54 (0.16) 0.01 (0.09) 0.19 (0.11) 0.06 (0.15) 0.04 (0.32) 0.19 (0.24) 0.27 (0.1) 0.24 (0.14) 0.65 (0.07) 0.64 (0.11) 0.59 (0.08) 0.65 (0.21) 0.57 (0.09) 0.59 (0.13) 0.62 (0.08) -0.3 (0.02) -0.28 (0.02) -0.32 (0.02) -0.29 (0.06) -0.28 (0.03) -0.26 (0.03) -0.34 (0.03) Number of observations (5) 32792 4997 2807 711 2697 2878 731 11221 8480 7934 7942 12555 7328 4992 1119 2444 1866 4034 Again, we estimated (9) for every PRODCOM 2002 2-digit product category (equivalent to NACE rev. 1.1 2-digit industry) with more than 500 observations separately in order to allow for different input coefficients for products from different industries. Once again, our results coincide with our expectations and show huge variations in the production function coefficients between products from different 2-digit industries. Also within 2-digit product categories we find high levels of variation in the coefficients, which is in line with our expectations as individual products naturally differ a lot despite the fact that they are 22 classified into the same 2-digit product category. Further, across firms individual products may experience a very different importance within their firms, leading to even more heterogeneity. Note that contrary to the firm level estimation, the coefficients have to be interpreted conditional on the output of other goods being constant. This does not allow to define the returns to scale straightforward as the sum of the input coefficients. Again we drop industries for which we computed negative output elasticities with respect to labor, capital, and intermediate inputs. Further, we would have to drop industries for with we computed positive values for 𝛽−𝑔 , which is never the case in our estimation.19 4.2 The effects of competition on the German manufacturing sector 4.2.1 Evolution of import competition and productivity Figure 1 shows the evolution of the value of imports from high income, low income, and the entire world to Germany. Throughout the time period in question, both TFP and import pressure have generally risen. This rise, however, is largely attributable to imports from low income countries, while the market share of our set of developed countries stayed virtually constant. Nonetheless, products originating from industrialized partners make up the bulk of German imports. Note that a large chunk of imports has been left out of the analysis, since we excluded direct neighbors and Eurozone members to eliminate potential bias from common productivity shocks to both countries. 19 As mentioned in section 3.2, equation (9) is only well defined when 𝛽−𝑔 < 0 and 𝛽𝑥 > 0 ,with 𝑥 = (𝑙, 𝑘, 𝑚), holds. 23 Figure 1 year c World c High-income countries Low-income countries c When we relate the import competition measures we derived from the above share of imports with our TFP estimates, we find substantial co-movement over time. Figure 2 presents the corresponding graphs were we normalized all measures to unity in our base year 2001. 24 Figure 2 year 𝐼𝑚𝑝𝑜𝑟𝑡industrialized industrialized 𝐼𝑚𝑝𝑜𝑟𝑡 𝑇𝐹𝑃 𝐼𝑚𝑝𝑜𝑟𝑡emerging Eyeballing the above graph, one could propose a positive relationship between lagged import pressure and TFP: E.g., both types of import pressures peak 2006-2007, which coincides with a peak in TFP in 2007-2008. After the crisis, both TFP and import competition rise again. These fluctuations around the business cycle, however, provide only limited evidence of the efficiency enhancing effects of competition. One can easily argue that both have a common source and their causal relationship need not exist. This already points to the problems of identification over time, which we will discuss in more detail when we present our identification strategy. We should also note that, in any case, the correlation in the above graph should not be interpreted causally. 4.2.2 Estimating the effect of import competition on firm level productivity Theoretically, increased competition should have a strong disciplining effect on firms: To combat their market share decreases, firms should be forced to lower prices and either accept lower mark-ups or decrease their costs per unit. Additionally, firms which cannot adapt will fall prey to their more productive competitors. This can be called the selection effect of competition. Together, they provide the rationale for competition policy as well as 25 market integration. To identify these channels, we rely on exogenous competitiveness increases in other countries, measured at the product level. This fine-grained measure of import shocks allows us to improve upon the previous literature: We can compare firms within the same industry, but with a different product mix, instead of relying on intraindustry comparisons prone to omitted variable bias. However, we will refrain from identifying our effects via firm fixed effects, i.e. over time, for three reasons: First, this specification would eliminate the selection channel: If a firm is forced out of the market due to a competition shock, a fixed effects estimator would drop the firm at precisely the moment we are most interested in. Because the selection mechanism is ignored, this will result in an underestimate of the economy-wide effect. Second, the pressure a firm experiences over time is also a choice variable: It likely fluctuates as firms adjust their product portfolio to move away from attacked products. In this case, even if this is the result of competition and even if it increases productivity, the resulting correlation might be negative: As new, uncompetitive products gain importance for the firm, the measured import pressure declines. The exploration of how increasing competition drives structural change of this sort lies beyond the scope of this paper and may be better addressed in a subsequent research project, but again, it leads to an underestimation of the true coefficients. Last, but not least, extensive pressure might induce firms to switch industries. This poses a problem for the estimation since the production function is different for each industry and TFP measures are thus not comparable across them. This would force us to restrict the sample to those firms which do not switch. Again, this would lead to a downward bias since firms reacting in a strong way are excluded, although they are especially interesting. For this reason, we stick to identification over different firms. In fact, one could call our baseline specification a repeated cross section within each year and industry: 𝐻𝑖𝑔ℎ 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝑇𝐹𝑃𝑖𝑡 = 𝐼𝑆𝑖𝑡−1 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 + 𝐼𝑆𝐿𝑜𝑤 + 𝐷𝑗∗𝑡 + 𝑁𝑢𝑚𝑃𝑡−1 + 𝐸𝑥_𝐼𝑡−1 (YX) 𝑖𝑡−1 Here, 𝐷𝑖∗𝑡 represents a year times 4-digit industry ( 𝑗 ) dummy. We additionally control for past values of the number of products ( 𝑁𝑢𝑚𝑃𝑡−1 ) and the export intensity ( 𝐸𝑥_𝐼𝑡−1 ), both of which insulate companies from competition in the domestic market. Table 3 shows the associated results. 26 Table 3 The effect of import competition on firm level productivity All firms Dep. variable: 𝑇𝐹𝑃𝑖𝑡 𝐻𝑖𝑔ℎ 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆𝑖𝑡−1 𝐿𝑜𝑤 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆𝑖𝑡−1 𝐸𝑥_𝐼𝑡−1 𝑁𝑢𝑚𝑃𝑡−1 Obs. R-squared Wald-F # of Clusters Split by firm type Single-product (3) (4) OLS IV (1) OLS (2) IV 0.0031*** (0.0009) 0.001* (0.0005) -0.0002* (0.0001) -0.0045*** (0.0007) 0.0043*** (0.0015) -0.0008 (0.0009) -0.0002* (0.0001) -0.0045*** (0.0007) 0.00246* (0.00127) 0.0004 (0.0007) 0 (0.0001) 0.003 (0.002) -0.0027** (0.0013) 0 (0.0001) - - 42,397 0.962 11452 42,397 0.962 351.2 11452 15,297 0.948 4658 15,297 0.948 195.6 4658 Multi- product (5) (6) OLS IV 0.0032*** (0.0011) 0.0015* (0.0008) -0.0003** (0.0001) -0.0037*** (0.0006) 0.0064*** (0.0023) 0.0002 (0.0013) -0.0004** (0.0002) -0.0038*** (0.0006) 26,885 0.968 7235 26,885 0.968 214.3 7235 Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Evidently, the beneficial effects of competition are almost exclusively derived from import competition from developed countries. The size of the measured effects is economically meaningful, but not improbably large. For example, our results indicate that if foreign firms from industrialized countries capture an additional percentage point of the market, this leads domestic firms to increase their productivity by 0.4%. Throughout our observation period, the average pressure from foreign industrialized countries rose by 2 percentage points, to which we would attribute a modest 0.8% TFP growth contribution. It is noteworthy that OLS and IV estimates differ, and sometimes greatly. This illustrates the importance of instrumenting import competition shocks properly. In this case, OLS seems to view competition in a more benign light than is actually warranted. Thus, positive selection seems to be dominant here: In order to make it into our sample, firms must exist for one year after experiencing a significant competition shock. This means they likely are more productive than their counterparts from the start, because more productive firms are more resilient in general. However, as we will see in future applications, there is also an opposite effect: Competition likely targets especially uncompetitive, i.e. unproductive sectors. This leads to a negative correlation between productivity and import competition shocks and biases coefficients downwards. 27 Competition from low income countries seems to have, if any, a negative effect – concentrated among single product firms. This is in line with a whole class of IO models, which all postulate some sort of ladder competition: Both the quality ladders of Grossman, Helpman (1999) or Crepón, Duguet & Mairesse (1998) and the technology ladders of Aghion et al. (2004) suggest that only competition from firms on the same ladder step or a bit below that can spur firms to innovate. This is because firms give up on catching competitors very far ahead. Only if they think that innovation will give them a perceivable chance to become technology leader will they start to innovate. An additional argument would be one of market size: If innovation carries fixed sunk costs, but gives a per-unit benefit to the producer, only big firms have an incentive to innovate. In this case, increasing competition, by redistributing market shares towards the top, will increase the innovation incentives of some firms, while hurting that of others. Such models are prominent in the literature on export and innovation (Bustos (2011)). However, the evidence is also in line with a technology transfer model of trade where it is often argued that the emergence of technologically rich products on the market facilitates imitation. To better understand the mechanisms behind the effects, we split the sample of firms into productivity quantiles. Both competing explanations predict different patterns of effects in this exercise: If German firms learn from technology rich imports, we would expect to see the biggest effects for very unproductive firms. If, however, the effect works through the fixed innovation costs or through firms competing to become technology leader, we would expect positive effects for productive and negative effects for unproductive firms. Table 4 presents the corresponding results, where 𝑄1 represents a dummy for the lowest productivity quintile, while 𝑄5 symbolizes a dummy for the highest productivity quintile. 28 Table 4 The effect of import competition on firm level productivity per productivity quantiles (1) OLS (2) IV 0.0013 (0.0011) 0.0005 (0.0008) 0.0006 (0.0012) 0 (0.0004) 0.0012 (0.0014) -0.0024*** (0.0005) -0.0004 (0.0003) 0.0005* (0.0003) 0.0008*** (0.0003) 0.0014*** (0.0006) 0.159*** (0.0036) 0.261*** (0.0036) 0.374*** (0.0039) 0.534*** (0.0061) 0 (0) -0.0014*** (0.0002) 0.0037** (0.0015) 0.0013 (0.0012) 0.00088 (0.0009) -0.0005 (0.0008) 0.0004 (0.0017) -0.0027*** (0.0007) -0.0009* (0.0005) 0 (0.0004) 0.0003 (0.0004) 0.0005 (0.0008) 0.162*** (0.004) 0.264*** (0.0041) 0.380*** (0.0044) 0.542*** (0.0068) 0 (0) -0.0014*** (0.0002) 42,397 0.981 11452 42,397 0.981 73.42 11452 Dep. variable: 𝑇𝐹𝑃𝑖𝑡 𝐻𝑖𝑔ℎ 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 ∗ 𝑄1 𝐻𝑖𝑔ℎ 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 ∗ 𝑄2 𝐻𝑖𝑔ℎ 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 ∗ 𝑄3 𝐻𝑖𝑔ℎ 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 ∗ 𝑄4 𝐻𝑖𝑔ℎ 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 ∗ 𝑄5 𝐼𝑆𝑖𝑡−1 𝐼𝑆𝑖𝑡−1 𝐼𝑆𝑖𝑡−1 𝐼𝑆𝑖𝑡−1 𝐼𝑆𝑖𝑡−1 𝐿𝑜𝑤 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆𝑖𝑡−1 ∗ 𝑄1 𝐿𝑜𝑤 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆𝑖𝑡−1 ∗ 𝑄2 𝐿𝑜𝑤 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆𝑖𝑡−1 ∗ 𝑄3 𝐿𝑜𝑤 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆𝑖𝑡−1 ∗ 𝑄4 𝐿𝑜𝑤 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆𝑖𝑡−1 ∗ 𝑄5 𝑄2 𝑄3 𝑄4 𝑄5 𝐸𝑥_𝐼𝑡−1 𝑁𝑢𝑚𝑃𝑡−1 Obs. R-squared Wald-F # of Clusters Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 The estimation again points to significant heterogeneity between different sources of competition: For industrialized countries, learning from imported goods seems to be the relevant channel, evident from the positive coefficients for low productivity firms. To the contrary, for low income countries, we find negative coefficients for unproductive ones. This is inconsistent with technology imitation and points to competition inducing investments in 29 productivity. This difference in channels seems plausible: Only highly developed countries will export technology that German firms will on average find worthwhile to innovate, Germany being a technology leader itself in many cases. While the products of low income countries are internationally competitive through lower wages, their quality and technology content is on average lower (Khandelwal (2010); Hummels, Klenow (2005)). Attacked domestic firms seemingly do not feel that investing in productivity helps them to cope with this. There are two theoretical explanations for this: First, perhaps there are in fact two separate markets for cheap and for technologically sophisticated products. In this case, if the consumers evidently prefer the cheap variant, investing in even more technological sophistication will not help firms. Second, endogenous growth models usually feature decreasing return to productivity investments. If this is the case, it might be simply to costly to innovate enough to be competitive with very low cost producers. In an Heckscher-Ohlin fashion, firms would cede products which can be produced with cheap labor to foreign competition. In fact, this is a prediction that also comes out of ladder-type models. All of the above arguments indicated that competition is a driver of productivity. However, somewhat unintuitive, we also find relatively strong negative effects. However, there is actually a compelling reason for these: If firms loose market share fast, they have to shrink. However, as already standardly argued when estimating a production function, labor and capital cannot be considered as fully flexible inputs. As a result, unexpectedly shrinking firms might end up with declining TFP, as unused inputs pile up. This implies that to reap the productivity benefits of sudden moves in competition, input market would have to be flexible. To our knowledge, this channel was not yet shown in the literature. When looking at multi-product firms, we can use their product portfolio to get a clearer picture of these effects. In the table below, we present an estimate where we compute the import pressure for the first product (𝐼𝑆_1𝑠𝑡𝑖𝑡𝑛 ) and all other products (𝐼𝑆_𝑂𝑡ℎ𝑖𝑡𝑛 ) separately, to find out through which channels product pressure affects the firm. 30 Table 5 The effect of import competition of firm level productivity separately Dep. variable: 𝑇𝐹𝑃𝑖𝑡 𝐻𝑖𝑔ℎ 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆_1𝑠𝑡𝑖𝑡−1 𝐿𝑜𝑤 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆_1𝑠𝑡𝑖𝑡−1 𝐻𝑖𝑔ℎ 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆_𝑂𝑡ℎ𝑖𝑡−1 𝐿𝑜𝑤 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆_𝑂𝑡ℎ𝑖𝑡−1 𝐸𝑥_𝐼𝑡−1 𝑁𝑢𝑚𝑃𝑡−1 (1) OLS (2) IV 0.0014 (0.001) 0.0001 (0.0006) 0.0028*** (0.001) 0.0005 (0.0006) -0.0003** (0.0002) -0.0036*** (0.0026) 0.0016 (0.0020) 0 (0.001) 0.0094*** (0.0023) 0.0006 (0.0009) -0.0004** (0.0002) -0.0036*** (0.0068) Obs. 26,254 R-squared 0.969 Wald-F # of Clusters 6965 Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 26,254 0.969 93.36 6965 Unexpectedly, we find that the productivity effect is concentrated among multi-product firms whose secondary product portfolio is threatened. However, it is consistent with the view that rigidities hinder firms from adjusting their size efficiently: We would expect that pressure on the first product generates the bulk of revenue losses. Without a hit to the first product, it seems unlikely that firms will be forced to lay off inputs at such a rate that input market frictions become a serious problem for them. However, we caution against interpreting this result too confidently for two reasons: One is theoretical: While intuitively, we would like to measure whether the effect of import competition is more pronounced on the first product, this is not equivalent of the above equation. To see this, take a big multinational firm as an example: If such a firm receives pressure on its core product, this might still only amount to a minuscule pressure overall, because the core product does not represent a big share of revenue. On the other hand, the same pressure over the whole product range would be felt by the firm. The second reason is that we observe some volatility in the estimated coefficients across specifications: While the results are always consistent with an overall positive effect of competition from 31 industrialized countries and a insignificant or negative effect of poorer trading partners, the coefficients for the first product and the rest are not as stable as we would like. While illustrative, this discussion only scratches the surface of the potential product data has in order to better understand the channels through which competition work. Thus, we will deepen the discussion of these effects by incorporating our product level results. 4.2.3 Firm-product TFP and import competition At the product level we use the following baseline specification: 𝐻𝑖𝑔ℎ 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝑇𝐹𝑃𝑔𝑖𝑡 = 𝐼𝑆𝑔𝑡−1 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 + 𝐼𝑆𝐿𝑜𝑤 + 𝐷𝑔∗𝑖+𝑡 , 𝑔𝑡−1 (11) were 𝐷𝑔∗𝑖+𝑡 captures time dummies and an interaction between product and firm dummies. Consequently, for identification we explore variation over time within a specific firmproduct. Like explained in chapter 3.4, we instrument import competition from country group 𝑛 to Germany with the share of imports on total imports in other markets with characteristics similar to Germany. Table 6 shows the associated results. Table 6 The effect of import competition of product level productivity (1) OLS (2) IV 𝐿𝑜𝑤 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆𝑔𝑡−1 0.0023 (0.0024) -0.0064*** (0.0011) 0.0018 (0.0087) -0.0124*** (0.0033) Obs. R-squared Wald-F # of Clusters 139,452 0.995 13676 100,476 0.995 75.90 10367 Dep. Variable: 𝑇𝐹𝑃𝑔𝑖𝑡 𝐻𝑖𝑔ℎ 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆𝑔𝑡−1 Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 As one can immediately see, instrumenting the import competition greatly improves the quantitative dimension of the coefficient for import competition from low income countries, while the significance of the import competition measure for high income countries stays unchanged. This results imply that among surviving products (products produced in 𝑡 and 32 𝑡 − 1) import competition from low income countries lead to negative productivity effects, while import competition from high income countries show no significant effects in this respect. The negative effects is in line with the results found at the firm level for single product firms and implies that a one percent increase in import competition from low income countries, measured by the share of imports on the domestic market, reduces the productivity of the average domestic firm-product by a considerable 1,2 percentage points. Notably, import competition from high income countries does not significantly effect the productivity of firm-products. Intuitively, when foreign goods are imported, market shares are transferred from domestic products towards foreign products. This forces firms to produce at a lower scale which already by itself can lead to negative productivity effects and which can be emphasized by frictions that prevent the firm from efficiently reorganizing their production activities, which in line with very recent findings that stress long labor market adjustment processes after import competition shocks from China at the sector level (Autor, Dorn, and Hanson (2016)). Further, seemingly firms cannot overcome those market share losses associated with import competition, at least not within one year, by investing in product productivity increasing process innovations. As low income countries, compared to a high income country like Germany, posses a production cost advantage due to lower wages, one can easily imagine that German firms want to avoid competing with producers from low wage countries and try to escape into other production activities. However, our results at the firm level show that such adjustment processes do not lead to an increase in productivity within the first year after the competition shock. To investigate further the effects of product level import competition on product level productivity, we interacted the import competition measure with the rank of a product within its firm (in terms of revenue shares), were products with a rank of 4 or higher are consolidated. Results are reported in Table 7. 33 Table 7 The effect of import competition on product level productivity conditional on the rank of a product Dep. Variable: 𝑇𝐹𝑃𝑔𝑖𝑡 𝐻𝑖𝑔ℎ 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆𝑔𝑡−1 ∗ 𝑅𝑎𝑛𝑘1 𝐻𝑖𝑔ℎ 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆𝑔𝑡−1 ∗ 𝑅𝑎𝑛𝑘2 𝐻𝑖𝑔ℎ 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 ∗ 𝑅𝑎𝑛𝑘3 𝐻𝑖𝑔ℎ 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 ∗ 𝑅𝑎𝑛𝑘4+ 𝐼𝑆𝑔𝑡−1 𝐼𝑆𝑔𝑡−1 𝐿𝑜𝑤 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆𝑔𝑡−1 ∗ 𝑅𝑎𝑛𝑘1 𝐿𝑜𝑤 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆𝑔𝑡−1 ∗ 𝑅𝑎𝑛𝑘2 𝐿𝑜𝑤 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆𝑔𝑡−1 ∗ 𝑅𝑎𝑛𝑘3 𝐿𝑜𝑤 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆𝑔𝑡−1 ∗ 𝑅𝑎𝑛𝑘4+ Time FE Firm * product FE Product * time FE Product * firm* product rank FE Obs. R-squared Wald-F # of Clusters Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 (1) OLS (2) IV 0.0094** (0.0038) -0.0024 (0.0032) -0.0057* (0.0033) -0.0103*** (0.0034) -0.0013 (0.0012) -0.0074*** (0.0013) -0.0092*** (0.0015) -0.0143*** (0.0018) YES YES NO NO 0.0314*** (0.0107) 0.0074 (0.0101) -0.0152 (0.0106) -0.0345*** (0.0124) 0.0012 (0.004) -0.0133*** (0.0039) -0.0227*** (0.0042) -0.0317*** (0.0049) YES YES NO NO 118,244 0.995 11474 85,372 0.996 14.02 8666 (3) OLS (4) IV -0.004* (0.0023) -0.0075** (0.0033) -0.0109*** (0.0032) -0.0064 (0.0046) -0.0178*** (0.0063) -0.0253*** (0.0071) -0.0022** (0.001) -0.0024* (0.0013) -0.0045*** (0.0016) NO NO YES YES -0.0074*** (0.0016) -0.0094*** (0.0023) -0.0124*** (0.0026) NO NO YES YES 100,340 0.998 10745 72,389 0.998 65.12 8055 The first two columns show results from a regression that includes the same fixed effects as the baseline specification, i.e. time and firm times product fixed effects, which can be referred as the within estimator. Column (3) and (4) complete this picture by looking across products within a firm and excluding all variation coming from products that switch their rank. Column (3) and (4) therefore, represent a comparison between the productivity effects of lagged import competition on product ranks within a firm, while column (1) and (2) are showing the absolute productivity effects of import competition. First of all, again we find that instrumenting the import competition shock amplifies the associated coefficients remarkably. We further see from Column (2) that import competition from high wage countries leads to highly positive productivity effects when the targeted product is the core product of a firm. 34 Quantitatively we find that a one percentage point increase in import competition form high wage countries leads to a product level productivity increase of roughly 3 percentage points when the core product of a firm is targeted. Interestingly, in both specifications we find that the lower the revenue share of a product subjected to import competition, the more negative is the productivity effect. This implies that firms skew their product mix towards their core products, which confirms theoretical models (e.g. Mayer, Melitz, Ottaviano 2014) and recent empirical findings (Dyhne et al. 2016). Furthermore, combining this results with our firm level estimates, positive productivity effects of import competition from high income countries at the firm level are asymmetrically distributed over the product mix of firms and indeed are partly associated with negative productivity effects. This in an important finding as it emphasizes distributional consequences. Workers associated with peripheral production processes may lose from import competitions shocks originating from high income countries, while workers associated with production processes that lie in the focus of the firm may benefit. Therefore our results stress the importance of product level analyses, as only investigating the firm level may overlooks important parts of the effects from import competition that are highly relevant for welfare questions as well as for the evaluation of trade policies. In line with our previous findings we see that import competition from low income/wage countries is only associated with negative productivity effects. Similar to the high income/wage case, those effects become increasingly negative when we move down the product ranking of the targeted product. 4.2.4 Labor reactions to import competition shocks During the analysis of the effects of intensifying competition on TFP, we came across several negative estimates, i.e. findings that TFP decreased with increasing competition. We argued that decreasing market shares force firms to shrink, which they cannot do as fast as would be appropriate due to input market frictions. This might cause the short-term TFP decline observed in the data. To test this hypothesis, we study the firms’ employment reaction in the wake of an import competition shock (Columns 1-4 of the below table). To estimate it, we swapped the dependent variable from Frim TFP to full-time-equivalents, but left the methodology unchanged otherwise, i.e. we control for industry times year fixed effects. 35 Table 8 Labour adjustments after import competition shock Dep. Variable: Full Time Equivalent of Labor 𝐻𝑖𝑔ℎ 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆𝑔𝑡−1 𝐿𝑜𝑤 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆𝑔𝑡−1 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) OLS IV OLS SP IV SP OLS IV -0.0116*** 0.00501 -0.00542* (0.00240) (0.00518) (0.00315) -0.00765*** -0.00575** -0.00556*** (0.00141) (0.00254) (0.00178) 𝐻𝑖𝑔ℎ 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆_1𝑠𝑡𝑖𝑡−1 𝐿𝑜𝑤 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆_1𝑠𝑡𝑖𝑡−1 𝐻𝑖𝑔ℎ 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆_𝑂𝑡ℎ𝑖𝑡−1 𝐿𝑜𝑤 𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑒 𝐼𝑆_𝑂𝑡ℎ𝑖𝑡−1 l_NumP l_Ex_I 0.0468*** (0.00645) 0.0114*** (0.000736) 79,636 Obs. 0.287 R-squared Wald-F 24247 # of Clusters Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 0.0469*** (0.00647) 0.0113*** (0.000731) 0.122*** (0.0213) 0.0102*** (0.000534) 79,636 0.285 581.6 24247 30,394 0.255 9752 0.00925 (0.00655) -0.00533* (0.00319) -0.0107*** 0.00798 (0.00278) (0.00690) -0.00730*** -0.00667** (0.00165) (0.00319) -0.00631** -0.00175 (0.00262) (0.00709) -0.00432*** -0.00325 (0.00156) (0.00266) 0.122*** 0.0383*** 0.0383*** (0.0214) (0.00546) (0.00547) 0.00999*** 0.0120*** 0.0118*** (0.000539) (0.00128) (0.00127) 30,394 0.252 271.3 9752 47,668 0.325 14651 47,668 0.322 212.6 14651 We can see that indeed, firms seem to lay off people in response to increased competition. However, while this correlation does appear to be causal in the case of low income countries, instrumentation reveals that the correlation breaks down in the case of high technology competition. Again, this points to learning effects as a central driver behind the productivity increase: Increased imports from industrialized countries seem to induce firms to become more productive. However, we should probably not put to much weight on the positive effect of competition on employment, given the big standard errors. Still, it seems pretty clear that negative employment effects from import competition are mainly originating from imports from low income countries which is in line with our previous results on firm and product level productivity and also reported in other studies (Acemoglu et al. (2013); Autor, Dorn, and Hanson (2016)). To quantify this effect: A one percentage point increase in competition from low wage countries leads to a more than 0.5% reduction of employment. This effect is remarkable stable across OLS and IV, as well as across single product firms and the whole population. In the last two columns, to better understand the dynamics for multi-product firms, we split 36 import pressure into pressure originating from the first product of the firms and the pressure resulting from the rest of the product portfolio. Thus, we can see that even for multiproduct firms, the effects work primarily through the core products of the firm. The very high skewness of the revenue distribution across firms and products documented throughout the literature in this case works against multi-product firms: If they had a portfolio of three equally important products, they would be able to mitigate the effects of lost revenue much better. As it is, they suffer to the same degree that single product firms do. From this evidence we can conclude that input market frictions which prevent efficient downsizing may indeed explain the negative effect of competition on productivity. This is plausible because negative productivity reactions coincide with downsizing, while growing productivity does not. This provides strong support for the idea that flexible input markets are a prerequisite to realize gains from trade. It should however also be pointed out that such flexibility comes at a cost not modelled here, which would have to be weighted against any additional productivity gains. 5 Conclusion This paper examines the casual effects of import competition on firm and firm-product level productivity of German manufacturing firms. We exploit our high level administrative data base to construct a quantity based measure of total factor productivity (TFPQ) which, contrary to revenue based measures is purged from undesired price effects that may bias true technical efficiency measures. We further, propose a simple intuitive solution to the critique of Gandhi et al. (2013), which normally would forbid using popular control function techniques like in Olley, Pakes (1996), Levinsohn, Petrin (2003) or Wooldridge (2009) to estimate a production function. Our study presents the first casual evidence on the potential different effects from import competition from different country sources on firm level and firm-product level productivity. We indeed find that the origin of international competition matters. While import competition from high wage countries is associated with firm productivity enhancing effects, import competition from low wage countries depresses firm productivity. To deepen our understanding on potential channels, we go one step further and look at the reactions at the firm-product level. Our results show that import competition 37 form high income countries leads to product productivity enhancing effects only if the targeted product is at the core of the production activities of a firm. Low wage import competition in general causes productivity decreases at the product level. In general, the more peripheral a product is, the more negative becomes the effect of import competition on productivity. Even where we find positive firm level effects, we find much more ambiguous results at the product level. This indicates that generally, firms do not achieve these productivity gains from improving their product lines. Instead, product portfolio adjustment seems to play the most important role. Our results imply that firms skew their product mix towards their core products when foreign competition shocks hit the firm, which confirms modern trade theories (e.g. Mayer, Melitz, and Ottaviano 2014). Furthermore, our study emphasizes the importance of product market analyses as firm level reactions partly disguise product market adjustments which have important welfare implications, especially for workers associated with peripheral production processes. We also investigate firm level labor adjustments and find that especially low wage import competition leads to a shrinking of firms. For international competition originating from high wage countries we cannot find any significant effects on the firms’ labor adjustment. This is in line with our results for total factor productivity and reinforces the strong contrast between the effects of import competition from different country sources. We therefore stress the great importance of country asymmetries when analyzing firm level consequences from international competition – an aspect which lately had remarkably sparse attention in empirical economic science. 38 References Ackerberg, D. A., Caves, K., & Frazer, G. (2015). Identification properties of recent production function estimators. Econometrica, 83(6), 2411-2451. Autor, David, David Dorn, and Gordon H. Hanson. "The China Syndrome: Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States." The American Economic Review, 103.6 (2013): 2121-2168. Correia, S. (2016a). REGHDFE: Stata module to perform linear or instrumental-variable regression absorbing any number of high-dimensional fixed effects. Statistical Software Components. Correia, S. (2016b). A Feasible Estimator for Linear Models with Multi-Way Fixed Effects. Manuscript. De Loecker, J., & Warzynski, F. (2012). Markups and firm-level export status. The American Economic Review, 102(6), 2437-2471. De Loecker, J., & Warzynski, F. (2012). Markups and firm-level export status. The American Economic Review, 102(6), 2437-2471. De Loecker, J., Fuss, C., & Van Biesebroeck, J. (2014). International competition and firm performance: Evidence from Belgium. Econstar Working Paper Research (No. 269). De Loecker, J., Goldberg, P. K., Khandelwal, A. K., & Pavcnik, N. (2016). Prices, markups, and trade reform. Econometrica, 84(2), 445-510. De Loecker, Jan, and Pinelopi K. Goldberg. "Firm Performance in a Global Market." Annu. Rev. Econ. 6.1 (2014): 201-227. 39 De Loecker, Jan, Catherine Fuss, and Johannes Van Biesebroeck. International competition and firm performance: Evidence from belgium. No. 269. National Bank of Belgium, 2014. De Loecker, Jan, et al. "Prices, Markups, and Trade Reform." Econometrica 84.2 (2016): 445510. Dhyne, Emmanuel, et al. "Multi-Product Firms, Import Competition, and the Evolution of Firm-product Technical Efficiencies." (2016). Foster, L., Haltiwanger, J., & Syverson, C. (2008). Reallocation, firm turnover, and efficiency: Selection on productivity or profitability?. The American economic review, 98(1), 394-425. Gandhi, A., Navarro, S., & Rivers, D. (2016). On the Identification of Production Functions: How Heterogeneous is Productivity?. Manuscript. Levinsohn, J., & Petrin, A. (2003). Estimating production functions using inputs to control for unobservables. The Review of Economic Studies, 70(2), 317-341. Mayer, Thierry, Marc J. Melitz, and Gianmarco I.P. Ottaviano. "Market size, competition, and the product mix of exporters." The American Economic Review 104.2 (2014): 495-536. Melitz, Marc J., and Gianmarco I.P. Ottaviano. "Market size, trade, and productivity." The review of economic studies 75.1 (2008): 295-316. Mueller, S. (2008). Capital stock approximation using firm level panel data. Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik, 228(4), 357-371. OECD (2013): OECD Indicators of Employment Protection. http://www.oecd.org. Olley, S., & Pakes, A. (1996). The dynamics of productivity in the telecomunications equipment industry. Econometrica, 64, 1263-97. Ornaghi, C., & Van Beveren, I. (2012). Semi-parametric estimation of production functions: A sensitivity analysis. Manuscript. 40 Petrin, A., & Levinsohn, J. (2012). Measuring aggregate productivity growth using plant‐level data. The RAND Journal of Economics, 43(4), 705-725. Wooldridge, J. M. (2009). On estimating firm-level production functions using proxy variables to control for unobservables. Economics Letters, 104(3), 112-114. Appendix A: Construction of capital series Our dataset does not contain direct information on the (accounting) capital stock. However, once we have a start capital stock, we can use investment data for the perpetual inventory method to construct a series of capital stocks. To estimate a start capital stock, we combine information on the value of the yearly depreciation of firms, 𝜋𝑖𝑡 , which is available in our data set, with information on the 2-digit industry ( 𝑗 ) specific average lifetime of capital goods bought in year 𝑡, 𝐷𝑡𝑗 (𝜃). Latter is provided by the statistical office of Germany and is subdivided in the categories, 𝜃, which are equipment and buildings. The expected lifetime of capital goods contains information about their real depreciation rate.20 We assume a constant depreciation rate of capital and that capital is destroyed (depreciated) at the end of the production period. Both are standard assumptions in the literature. To ease notation we suppress the index 𝜃, noting that it makes no difference for our derivation. We define the number of machines which were destroyed during the production process in industry 𝑗 and period 𝑡 as: 𝜑𝑗𝑡 ≡ 𝛿𝑡 ′ 𝑗 ∗ 𝐾𝑗𝑡 , where 𝛿𝑡 ′ 𝑗 is the depreciation rate of capital purchased at time 𝑡 ′ . The average lifetime of a capital stock purchased in year 𝑡 = 0 then equals: 20 Using this relationship rests on an idea of Müller (2008). We augment his approach by specifying an exact functional form for the depreciation of capital that is consistent with assuming a linear depreciation of capital (i.e. a regressive function of the surviving capital stock). 41 ∞ 𝐷0𝑗 ∞ 1 1 = ∑ 𝜑𝑗𝑡 ∗ 𝑡 = ∑(𝛿0𝑗 𝐾𝑗𝑡 ) ∗ 𝑡 . 𝐾𝑗0 𝐾𝑗0 0 (𝑋𝑋𝑋) 0 By using the law of motion for a linear capital depreciation, 𝐾𝑗𝑡 = 𝐾𝑗0 ∗ (1 − 𝛿0𝑗 )𝑡 , and substituting it into (XXX), one can show with some algebra, that the following equation holds: −𝛿 (𝜃) 0𝑗 𝐷0𝑗 (𝜃) = ln(1−𝛿 .21 0𝑗 (𝜃)) We solve this expression numerically for each year and each capital type (equipment and buildings). This generates two depreciation rates for each industry and point in time. We then define a single depreciation rate by using weights from the industry wide stocks of equipment and buildings at time 𝑡. Further, we simplify by assuming that the depreciation rate for the whole capital stock in each period equals the depreciation rate of newly purchased capital in this period, i.e. 𝛿𝑡 ′ 𝑗 = 𝛿𝑡𝑗 . Having 𝛿𝑡𝑗 , we can calculate a start capital stock for firm 𝑖 by using the data on yearly depreciations, deflated by an industry specific capital depreciation deflator coming from the statistical office of Germany: 𝜋 𝜋𝑖𝑡 = 𝛿𝑡𝑗 ∗ 𝐾𝑖𝑡 → 𝐾𝑖𝑡 = 𝛿 𝑖𝑡 . 𝑡𝑗 After having the start capital stock, we construct our capital series by using the following law of motion: 𝐾𝑖𝑡 = 𝐾𝑖𝑡−1 (1 − 𝛿𝑗𝑡−1 ) + 𝐼𝑖𝑡−1 , Where 𝐼𝑖𝑡−1 is last years firm specific investment, deflated by an industry specific investment deflator (Source: statistical office of Germany). We therefore assume that Investment takes one year to be available in production. 21 The prove is available on request. 42 Our capital stock has several advantages over the usual ones used in literature. First we do not need to assume a arbitrary depreciation rate.22 Second, our depreciation rate is industry and time specific, taking care of the fact, that capital stocks deviate between industries. Third, our capital stock is closer to the productive capital stock, i.e. the capital used in production, rather than the usual capital stocks used throughout the literature, which are normally based on accounting data.23 22 Often one simply says that 𝛿𝑡𝑗 is time constant and equals 8%, which, in our case, would be a noteworthy deviation from the calculated depreciation rate. 23 Capital stocks from accounting data can be a poor approximation of the real capital used in the production process, because firms’ have an incentive to depreciate their accounting capital excessively high. 43
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz