Housing and Governance Why Regulatory Reform is Part of the Problem and Part of the Solution Josef Konvitz Working Papers m 2011:06 Adam Smith Research Foundation Working Papers Series 2011:06 The Working Papers series is intended to reflect the diverse range of interdisciplinary research interests of staff in the College of Social Sciences at the University of Glasgow. By publishing papers as works in progress, it aims to encourage and promote the interdisciplinary research work of members of the College, and to provide a forum in which to share innovative ideas and approaches on interdisciplinary topics, and elicit feedback from peers before submitting to more formal refereed peer review in the form of conference papers or journal articles. To this end, the author’s contact details for correspondence are normally provided in each paper. Submissions: Papers authored by one or more members of College staff can be submitted to the ASRF (via the email address below) to be considered for publication. Texts should normally be no longer than 8,000 words, and should be submitted in a Microsoft Word-compatible (.doc or .rtf) file format. Authors are advised to keep in mind the generalist audience of the Working Papers series and avoid technical language and extensive footnotes as much as possible. m The Adam Smith Research Foundation (ASRF) is based within the College of Social Sciences at the University of Glasgow, and aims to promote and sustain research within the UK, European and international arenas. The Foundation promotes the engagement of staff in key policy debates and in shaping policy for the future. It provides the environment in which to foster further links between the College’s disciplines and supports the development of interdisciplinary research both within and beyond the University. The Foundation seeks to honour the Enlightenment legacy of Adam Smith (1723-1790) with independent, original research that impartially advances knowledge in the Information Age. It aims to support and encourage interdisciplinary research and collaboration within seven cross-College Research Themes: . Globalisation, Competitiveness and Sustainability . Governance, Policy, Accountability and Risk Management . Health and Wellbeing . Inequalities, Inclusion, Identities and Social Change . Justice, Rights, Security and Conflict . People, Places, Engagement and Change . Learning Across the Professions Adam Smith Research Foundation College of Social Sciences University of Glasgow 66 Oakfield Avenue Glasgow G12 8LS Tel: +44 (0)141 330 7656 / 3494 email: adamsmith-asrf@glasgow.ac.uk www.glasgow.ac.uk/asrf © University of Glasgow 2011 The University of Glasgow, charity number SC004401 Working Papers m 2011:06 Housing and Governance Why Regulatory Reform is Part of the Problem and Part of the Solution Josef Konvitz November 2011 Adam Smith Research Foundation . Working Papers Series About the author Josef Konvitz recently retired as Head of Regulatory Policy in the OECD’s Directorate for Public Governance and Territorial Development. The Regulatory Policy Division carries out studies on risk and regulation, regulatory management indicators, administrative simplification, multi-level regulatory coherence, and public service delivery. Professor Konvitz has directed country reviews of regulatory reform of Australia,, China, Russia, France, Sweden, and Switzerland, and monitoring exercises of Japan, Mexico and Korea. He was responsible for the updating of OECD recommendations on regulatory reform, now the 2005 Guiding Principles for Regulatory Quality and Performance, and for the preparation of the APEC-OECD Integrated Checklist for Regulatory Reform. Since 2008 he has supervised co-operation between the OECD and Mexico on Regulatory Reform. Professor Konvitz joined the OECD in 1992 in the Urban Affairs Division after nearly twenty years on the faculty of Michigan State University. His work on urban policy at the OECD has included reviews of Metropolitan Melbourne and Metropolitan Athens, as well as the Urban Renaissance Reviews (Belfast in 1999, Krakow in 2000, Canberra and Glasgow in 2001, Berlin and Kitakyushu in 2002). He directed a study on urban indicators, the Ecological City project, and a major report on Distressed Urban Areas; he organised the OECD-Australia Conference on Cities and the New Global Economy; and he supervised country reviews of Japan, Mexico and Germany related to urban policy and infrastructure. Professor Konvitz holds degrees from Cornell University (BA with Honours in History, 1967), and Princeton University (PhD in History, 1973). He is Honorary Professor of Education at the University of Glasgow. Address for correspondence Prof. Josef Konvitz, c/o Adam Smith Research Foundation, College Research Office, College of Social Sciences, University of Glasgow, 53 Hillhead Street, Glasgow G12 8QF. Email: Josef.Konvitz@glasgow.ac.uk 2 Introduction: Policy Failure? Political Misjudgment? T he “regulatory governance gap” in housing policy has widened glaringly since 2007. This matters all the more because governments are far more reliant on the regulatory lever now that their room for manoeuver to use fiscal and monetary instruments is severely constrained. A wholesale review of housing policies, from credit and banking to building codes and permits was overdue in the run-up to the crisis. But the crisis has made the prospects for serious reform even less likely. Proposals for specific macro- and micro-economic reforms are advanced earnestly by people in government, the private sector and the academy in pursuit of recovery. These however are not backed up by proposals for effective evidence-based regulatory design and implementation. Regulatory reform in housing must address three challenges: risk management, cross-sectoral coordination, and multi-level coherence. Twenty years after regulatory policy gained prominence in government, reforms are still being recommended as if execution is a simple matter of executive power: just do it. Eager to be seen to do something, governments may jump to conclusions about what ought to be done, adopting reforms better suited to correcting the problems of the past rather than preparing for the urban economy of the future, without taking the time to carry out a strategic reassessment of housing policy based on the future needs of society. Frustrated by the slow pace of reform, politicians may be tempted to bypass or suspend sound regulatory practices, practices which the regulatory officials of OECD countries defended in 2008 when the crisis unfolded: evidence-based decision-making, transparency, consultation. The first part of this paper will highlight the governance challenges to a more coherent and sustainable set of macro- and micro-economic housing policy instruments; the second will question assumptions about the macroeconomic and social benefits of increased housing market flexibility and higher levels of home ownership; the final part, based on the future aspirations and needs of the middle class, presents the outlines on which a package of sustainable urban housing policy reforms could be made acceptable. case, macroeconomic, perspective. Since the early 2000s, reports and news articles have been tracking the upward trend in house prices, identifying the early symptoms of an asset bubble and outlining possible scenarios that might follow from actions taken by central banks and governments. Policy makers knew then what to do: there was no lack of information about packages of short-term, reversible and of long-term and permanent policy measures to bring housing supply and demand into better balance – and of the risks and costs of not doing so. Yet little was done: not only was it easy to procrastinate; it was also hard to see how reforms could be implemented, and translated into political gains. The only remaining option then was to wait to act until a crisis, in the hope that the crisis would not make reform even more difficult, as indeed is now the case. Sometimes a crisis makes policy reform easier: this was the case in 1990-92 when housing imploded in Housing policy reform is a governance challenge, operating on all levels of government and across sectors. Critical to the making of the crisis, housing is emblematic of the kind of “blind spot” when policymakers focus on a topic from a narrow, and in this 3 Adam Smith Research Foundation . Working Papers Series several countries (UK, Australia, Sweden, Finland, Japan, the US), with recessionary consequences – a large stock of unsold new properties, negative equity, etc. Reforms (but not in the US) included changing the deductibility of interest payments on primary and/or secondary residences, and changes in conveyancing arrangements to reduce churning that feeds an asset bubble. The crisis of 2008 and its aftershocks in 2011 however do not bear comparison: recession has taken over in many countries, and elsewhere in the developed world growth is low; the banking system is more exposed, and alternate forms of investment for individuals are less attractive: low interest rates and flight to safety which together still support the housing market in many countries make it more difficult to persuade the public of needed reforms that could affect their decisions about when to buy or sell. The situation is unprecedented, an inversion of the 1930s. During the inter-war years, the level of political skill, what the ancient Greeks, who knew a lot about government and geo-politics, called nous, was very high, but the theoretical and applied knowledge at hand during the Great Depression was deficient, even flawed. Today we know better what to do than how to do it: analysis is not the shortcoming, political skill is. Closing the governance gap, to reform housing policy instruments against new objectives, will not be easy. The combination of re-regulation in housing finance, and de-regulation in matters related to planning, permits, codes, conveyancing and the like, will be especially difficult to synchronize in time and to co-ordinate across regions and localities. Fiscal consolidation and the budget in the United States, and the problems of debt in the Eurozone, also highlight governance problems, and make it impossible for governments to provide assistance to those who stand to lose from reform. There is a tendency to fall back on technocratic solutions, without remedying the institutional or cultural faults that weaken trust in government. The political economy of housing reform weighs against reformers, in part because of the sheer complexity of a reform package, in part because millions of people who have not lost either their homes or their jobs may feel threatened by reforms, and in part because many micro-reforms are more a matter of local and regional or state authorities than of central governments. Meanwhile the constituency for reform – those who would benefit – has probably shrunk as economic insecurity and fiscal consolidation squeeze the middle class further. Maybe the electoral dynamics 4 for reform were already weak in the first years of the 21st century, when reforms might have been easier; we are where we are now. Little will be gained by pretending that the countries in which housing asset bubbles and financial reforms generated the crisis of 2008 belong in a separate category from the rest. The problems of policy coherence are widespread, shared across countries, those which have suffered a housing crash, those which are vulnerable to one, and those which appear relatively immune to a collapse. Housing policy is a governance problem, with a high degree of complexity. There are major problems of voice and exit when those who have most to gain from reform are often newcomers, relatively powerless, or both. Crosscountry comparisons, which by definition tell us more about the past than the present, are limited by severe problems of methodological comparability. Housing is therefore a test – perhaps the test – to overcome the tyranny of the silos. The term “paradigm shift” is often over-used and abused, but in this context it is almost an under-statement. Housing and the Factors of Growth Problems in housing today are not self-correcting: there are grounds for intervention. But policymakers are “pushing on a wet string” when trying to use traditional remedies which worked in the past. To continue to address problems in the sector without taking account of what has changed in our economies and societies – and to transform these changes into opportunities – is to hold back the transition to the economy of the future. This paper concludes with three: aging, green growth and risk reduction. Housing helps to clarify what has changed to the factors of growth, and what needs to change in public policy and social expectations. This extends beyond those countries – Ireland, Iceland, the UK, the US, Spain – where housing, and especially the links to banking on the one hand, and employment in construction on the other, are key to understanding the triggers of the crisis and its longevity. The expansion that preceded the crisis was nearly twice as long as the average of 6 years; and real house prices increased by 120% on average in a survey of 18 OECD countries (as against an average of around 45% in previous expansions). When it comes to construction in general as well as housing issues in particular, no aspect of this sector is exempt Housing and Governance . Konvitz from governance problems. Construction is the largest sector in employment: 7% of the EU workforce, more than 40 million people in the EU, the US and Japan before the crash of 2008, representing 6.47% of GDP. Does recovery mean returning to the volume of new housing starts in 2008, when housing markets were already disturbed by the perverse incentives and expectations of an asset bubble? What would be an appropriate level of construction during the crisis? In a recovery? Can housing lead a recovery when new housing starts and property investment are usually a lagging indicator? In an argument about resource allocation, is it reasonable for an economy to see 15% or more of its workforce employed in construction? The components which sustained the housing sector and supported the upward mobility of millions in the middle class in the post-1945 era have either weakened considerably, or gone into reverse. 1. Population is no longer growing in many OECD countries, or is growing at a low rate; yet new housing starts remains an important economic indicator, suggesting that more is better. The fact that more than half of the world’s population is now urban – a percentage that is expected to rise to 60% by 2030 – is itself a remarkable achievement, based on economic opportunity and the reorganization of vast networks for food and energy supply – but this statistic by itself does not tell us how much housing needs to be constructed or renovated, nor where. Urbanisation is irreversible, but individual cities do not grow or decline at average rates. The vast internal migration in most developed countries from rural to urban regions, and from city to city, often across hundreds of kilometers, ended years ago. Nevertheless, housing policies which dated from the end of World War One and the Great Depression, when millions needed housing with minimally decent facilities, have remained largely unchanged, in disregard to altered social and economic circumstances. Population growth is not the only driver of demand, of course: there are also changes in household size, as more people live in one- or two-person households (sometimes as much as 50% of a large city); ageing creates a different dynamic, especially when people can remain independent but need a safer environment inside and out, and a different mix of services, than may be found in the dwelling or community where they had lived for many years. Facile and simplistic assumptions are often made about the impact of an ageing population on housing demand; crude extrapolations from the recent past, when conditions were different from what they are now, should be questioned. Nevertheless, in many countries the housing stock is already in excess to the number of households – a pattern which could yet spread. 2. New cities are not under development in western countries, and cannot be initiated as easily as in the past, before concerns about climate change and other environmental risks, or about sustainability more generally, entered onto the public stage. Some cities are still growing, but many are mostly stable, and some are declining (a trend unheard of in the western world in the 20th century). This has implications for those who argue that land use regulations need to be relaxed in order to promote an expansion of the supply of housing, thereby reducing upward pressure on the price of real estate and encouraging sales. What may be needed in metropolitan areas which are already built-up to make better use of vacant or damaged land is not what other places need to contain the loss of land on the urban fringe. The overall building stock in cities changes at the rate of 1%-2% annually, meaning that it takes decades to remake a city through the process of demolition/new construction. Incremental change may be good, but it also has the effect of making planning rather too much of a theoretical exercise – by the time a ten-year or twenty-year plan has reached its use-by date, many of the variables that went into its development will have changed, perhaps significantly. 5 Adam Smith Research Foundation . Working Papers Series Housing policies continue to favour new construction on greenfield sites over intraurban renewal. As a result, land is converted to housing or to urban economic activities such as manufacturing or logistics. Urban activities are taking up more land at a rate greater than the rate of population growth. Between 1990 and 2000, the increase of artificial surfaces for housing, urban green areas, industry, commerce and transport was around 1,000 km2 per year within the 27 states of the European Union (already highly urbanized), or about 275 hectares per day, rising by 5.7% from 176,150 km2 to 186,200 km2. As an order of magnitude, this is equivalent to the making of a city exceeding the size of Berlin in a single year. By 2006, the total figures had increased to 191,2000 km2, indicating that the rate of land take was weakening. But of course this overall pattern masks regional differences (Prokop et al, 2011; see also MacDonald et al, 2010). Moreover, in some countries, the amount of urban land per family is greater than in others; many cultural, political and environmental variables need to be taken into account. There is no single benchmark of how much space per capita is enough, or when people start to over-consume. What matters is that the trend to convert land into urban space continues upwards. In the end, we reach the conclusion that undeveloped land is being consumed with implications for water management and global climate change, without necessarily gaining the benefits of agglomeration effects associated historically with urban development so necessary to achieving an optimal outcome. 3. Rights are often linked to housing. Property rights, including the right to privacy within one’s dwelling and to transfer title, have been fundamental elements of the social and political structure, in some regions for centuries, conveying both voting rights and fiscal obligations. It is worth remembering that agrarian societies often limited physical mobility through tenure arrangements that tied people to estates. Policy objectives to promote home ownership in the 20th century were inspired by the belief that by giving even the lower middle class a financial stake in an asset and in a community, the attraction of socialism, or worse, of communism, would be weakened. But government has failed to provide uniform public services of sufficient quality to all 6 neighborhoods. It is no wonder that people defend acquired rights when housing tenancy often correlates with exclusive access to better schools and environmental amenities. It is hard to anticipate what new right people will enjoy that is linked to the ownership of property. Civic rights, which in the past had been linked to ownership of property above a certain value, are now universal, irrespective of wealth or mode of tenure. Tenants, for example, can vote on the same issues as property owners even though their respective interests may be affected differently by the outcome. Concern over whether housing is a justiciable right, one which can be enforced in the courts, one which implies that states must provide housing at least under certain conditions, proved to be divisive during the Habitat II UN Conference on Human Settlements, in Istanbul, 1996. Several OECD countries took the position that housing is a basic right, to be enshrined in law and even in a constitution; others, including the United States, could not concur, out of concern to create a new entitlement for citizens. Yet the government of a modern nation that is “ill-fed, ill-clothed and ill-housed” would have to intervene, as the government of the United States did in fact during and after the Great Depression, with a legacy of institutions and policies that has proved immune to serious reform. 4. Innovation, the fourth factor of growth, is less apparent in the housing sector – discounting, of course, recent innovations in housing finance which turned out to cause unprecedented losses. We live in houses where people have lived before: what has changed is the sanitary plumbing, methods for heating, cooking and cooling, lighting, and the like – but within a physical structure which can still be used much as it had been generations ago. Many vernacular modes of building have virtues which are of considerable value for risk reduction (houses on stilts that survive flooding) or climate extremes (naturally ventilated structures in Yemen, heavy snow in northern Michigan). But innovation in the form of research on construction methods, building materials, land-use development, renovation and conversations, controlling risks and environmental externalities, and Housing and Governance . Konvitz so on is under-funded, compromised by the large number of small home-builders, by the complexity of building and design codes and zoned land uses which fragment markets and inhibit the adoption of new techniques, and by community resistance based on fear of change. Innovation, including in governance techniques to find social, cultural and political acceptance for new ways of constructing, renovating and using housing, is a priority on the way to sustainability. To conclude, housing is linked to each of the four factors that affect growth, but in ways that show how much more conservative it is than many other sectors, less open to innovation, more strongly linked to codes, contracts and other legally binding instruments. Housing, Housing Policy, and Policy-Making The fact that the building up of the city is itself an undertaking that helps to sustain both capital (for investors and owners) and capitalism (in the form of a market system which co-ordinates supply and demand) makes the current crisis even more important. If the demand for building declines, labour will be reallocated to other sectors, local authorities will have to be find other sources of revenue than licensing and permits associated with construction and land use change, financial institutions will have to diversify further from lending for property development and from holding property as collateral. The challenge, as we will see, is to maintain and even increase the positive agglomeration effects of cities and their metropolitan regions so as to maintain demand for housing, for quality institutional facilities and places of work, thereby contributing to the growth of productivity and of human capital. Market failures justify intervention. Frederich Hayek, in a chapter in Constitution and Liberty (1960), focused his attack not on those who abused the opportunities of the market as much as on the high political and economic cost of trying to achieve a more optimal outcome through administrative action and centralized planning. In the postwar era, government provision of housing using industrialised methods was still seen as both progressive and cost-effective. The quality of economic analysis related to housing, which Hayek found inadequate in his day, has improved, but is still subject to the criticism that important, generalized findings cannot be supported by narrow studies using different methodologies in a field in which the relative consequences of different variables are impossible to discriminate precisely. One solution favored by public choice theorists has been to devolve decision-making close to the people whose lives are most clearly affected by it. Many aspects of housing policy therefore are the domain of local and regional governments. In the 2011 edition of its survey of economic policy reforms, Going for Growth, the macroeconomists of the OECD took up the challenge of recommending measures to dampen volatility in residential housing investment, to facilitate residential mobility, and to couple appropriate regulatory oversight and prudent banking regulations with innovations in mortgage markets. Deregulation contributed to the rise in house prices by as much as 30% in the average OECD country between 1980 and 2005. Improving banking supervision, and reducing the maximum loan-to-value ratio by 10 percentage points, would reduce real house price volatility by nearly half. Policy-makers fall back on advice based on macroeconomic theory about how markets should work, advice which is difficult to put into practices, and which may not align with trends about spatial development. The more flexible the housing system, Housing, as a major factor in city-building, has become a hybrid in policy terms, partly a key element in the formation of capital and thus embedded in market practices and institutions, and partly itself a major focus of public policy, to correct for the social and environmental inequities which accumulated in the late 19th and early 20th centuries and re-emerge in an attenuated form. Given the density, size and complexity of cities, it is no wonder that the proper coordination between policies to promote effective and efficient markets, and to provide adequately for public goods, is so difficult. 7 Adam Smith Research Foundation . Working Papers Series the greater the likelihood that demand pressures will not push up prices. Oversimplified, the policy packages being recommended today call broadly for more and better financial regulation, and for less regulation at local level for planning, codes, permits and the like. Housing policy instruments which are fiscal and monetary remains are under the responsibility of national governments. The tools that affect the location of housing and, indirectly, its cost or benefit, such as planning, building codes and the like however are subject to local and regional regulation, and are poorly integrated into national housing policy, which lacks the ability to restrain credit, for example, in areas where local governments are facilitating the growth of the housing supply, while improving market conditions in other jurisdictions which are over-regulated. Construction and Land Use The OECD’s Competition Committee devoted two Roundtables on Competition Policy in 2008 to related issues: #86 on Land Use Restrictions as Barriers to Entry (OECD, 2008a), and #87 on Competition in the Construction Industry (OECD, 2008b). Competition in construction is handicapped by a number of factors, including regulatory barriers associated with licensing skilled labor and the division of work by craft-based skills on sites, issues related to the trade in imported materials and products, and building codes themselves. Local building firms , which tend to be small, therefore have market advantages which also limit the size of local markets. Successful large firms, which tend to work on large projects, are also favored by a proven record which may be a precondition for tendering. The business of house-building has more in common with 19th century commercial practices, including debt financing and estate development, than most other 21st century industries. Fragmentation has deterred research into new construction methods or materials; the post-war pursuit of mass production and large-scale site assembly, which reconstruction and mass migration made imperative, has reverted to earlier forms of housing supply. After enumerating the benefits of intervention to protect public goods, the environment, and communities, to minimize negative externalities, and to distribute the costs of providing public services more equitably, the OECD background paper highlighted the costs of land use restrictions, which include delays in starting a new business (and possibly even preventing competitive entry), thus increasing costs to 8 consumers. Delays are not only a matter of time while administrative procedures are under way, but also engender expenditure to prepare the paperwork, and to pay fees. Much of the concern is about delays that affect business operations, and the location of new retail facilities. (The OECD, in a unique programme of co-operation with the Ministry of Economy of Mexico, has identified the most significant obstacles in the process of reviewing applications for land use and construction permits in selected municipalities and states in Mexico, and has set out a handbook to guide officials in their efforts to improve and reform these procedures; the OECD is monitoring and evaluating the efforts of some jurisdictions to implement the handbook, in order to identify and diffuse good practices. The results should translate into more pro-active, aggressive efforts to launch or expand businesses.) Good site assembly may well explain the lower profit margins and higher building volumes of some Continental countries when compared with the UK. Some of the same problems associated with land use permits affect housing as well, when permits have to be granted, and sites have to be assembled: delays can also reflect local opposition, leading to two well-known syndromes, the Banana effect (“build absolutely nothing near anybody”), and Nimby-ism (“not in my back yard”). Regulatory uncertainty – not being able to anticipate the outcome of an administrative procedure such as a permit application or occupancy permit – deters investment. Planning and zoning affect the prices of houses, but studies, the OECD concluded, are not robust, making it difficult to determine the impact of specific variables. Changes to rules, an intensely political process, take place on the margin, leaving basic regulatory structures, themselves the result of very considerable political and legal battles nearly a century ago, in tact. The complexity of reform matters at a time when transparency is critical to anti-corruption, when stakeholders and the public must be consulted according to codified procedures, when decisions can be appealed through the courts, - in other words, when public participation, with all its strengths and shortcomings, must be taken into account. The logic for reform from the perspective of competition policy may be strong, but little will be done in the absence of a compelling plan to implement reforms - reforms which will generate opposition from some community and business interests - at all levels of government. Consider the advice given by Alan Mallach and Jennifer S. Vey in their 2011 article, “Recapturing Housing and Governance . Konvitz Land for Economic and Fiscal Growth” for the Brookings-Rockefeller Project on State and Municipal Innovation. Older industrial cities contain land that can be redeveloped, and Sunbelt cities have the highest foreclosure rates in the United States. The authors target tax foreclosure laws and laws that limit the ability of local governments to take control of abandoned properties efficiently. This is a strategy for bottom-up regeneration, for which funds are needed either through new appropriations or reallocations, not for fundamental housing policy reform. If local governments could gain control of properties and then manage and sell them in ways that are consistent with and help realize long-term development goals, the negative effects of foreclosures on adjacent properties would be abated, and the impact on the local tax base would be capped. But the suggestion that states should reform laws and regulations to give local governments the necessary set of legal and regulatory tools to levy a vacant property registration fee, to make creditors responsible for code violations, to create land bank authorities with powers to receive and resell properties, and to permit local governments to foreclose more quickly on tax delinquent properties can only be implemented through the political process, which itself remains handicapped by the lack of consistent state policies and strategies. The limited scope for local and state authorities to interfere in the property market reflects a long-standing belief that the rights of individual property-owners are a major check on arbitrary power. The authors cite as positive examples laws in Michigan and Ohio, but even in these states which have been in a prolonged recession with high unemployment it took years of decline before lawmakers were willing to enact reforms. The argument of a desperate last resort puts a stigma on what should be seen as a positive initiative. To be clear: land-use planning and infrastructure planning and expenditure may be devolved onto local and regional governments in both centralized and federated systems. But increasingly, issues about the future are like nesting boxes: the smaller boxes must fit into the larger ones, and the larger ones have to make room for the smaller ones. Regional and local plans must take account of national programmes and objectives for energy, clean air and water, pollution and remediation, and disaster reduction, to mention just the usual suspects, and issues of trans-border co-operation, inward investment, competitiveness, and sustainable agriculture often play a role. Because housing fixes land use patterns into private property, the cost of making changes through policy to a housing pattern can be overwhelming, and are certainly beyond the means of deficit-conscious governments for the foreseeable future. A regulatory reform strategy The advice of macroeconomists for more structural and micro housing reforms at the local level is rarely backed up by an analysis of the obstacles to regulatory reform, or of the strategies to make reform happen. The resulting blockage leads to an overall sense of impotence. Progress has been made in recent years to improve multi-level regulatory coherence, to strengthen public participation and transparency, to reduce regulatory and bureaucratic barriers, to integrate environmental and regulatory impact assessments and to carry out both ex-ante and ex-post impact analysis – but the full set of regulatory tools and institutions has yet to be brought to bear on the housing policy agenda. What would a regulatory reform programme for the housing sector look like? As a process it would have to bring together the credit system, land use and regional development, builders and inspectors, and all the sectors responsible for local service provision, from transport and waste management to health and education. In other words, a whole-of-government approach would be needed, one sufficiently broad and flexible moreover to take account of extreme local variations. This is not a quick fix to the economic consequences of the crisis, the fall in construction activity, and the problem of negative equity. Attention must be paid as well to the tools that local government need to make appropriate decisions, ranging from cadasters and data about environmental conditions and risks, to the facilities to process permit applications and handle appeals. Conveyancing requirements and their associated costs, rental regulations, building codes, land use planning and 9 Adam Smith Research Foundation . Working Papers Series permit systems, are embedded in professional practice and administrative structures. Regulatory governance calls for ways to co-ordinate across sectors and levels of government, and to involve the business and professional actors who make housing systems work in the private sector understand and accept reform. And this will take political leadership. Wholesale reviews of regulations for specific aspects of housing and construction could be undertaken by task forces working against deadlines, as long as there is also time for wider consultation, to assess the overall result. Regulatory risk management is needed for the financial sector, and to reduce the vulnerability of housing to disaster, to control corruption at the local level, and to anticipate moral hazard problems due to government intervention. Regulatory multi-level coherence covers high administrative costs, unnecessary and timeconsuming delays for land use or occupancy permits, the impact of fees on local government budgets, problems of weak enforcement, obsolete or excessively costly building codes, questions of zoning, and in general, the misalignment between national and local demands and objectives. Regulatory policy coherence addresses the problem of co-ordinating health, education, transport and the environment. There is no easy solution to the governance challenges of housing policy reform. If as is likely fiscal reforms and reforms of financial instruments for housing recommended at the central level are more likely to be implemented than reforms at the subnational level, , the result will be to further enhance the power and influence of housing finance in the overall policy package for housing. Macroeconomists cannot be blamed for putting the emphasis of their analysis of housing markets on macro-economic stability. But no one should have any illusions that the full package of policy instruments that affect housing can or will be reformed comprehensively. 10 The Policy Objectives for Housing: The beliefs embedded in macroeconomic and social policy that helped get us into this mess and inhibit reform The question of what should be reformed cannot be separated from the assumptions about how housing markets should function. Macro-economists call for regulatory reforms of real estate markets, to reduce transaction costs and increase turn-over, of planning to expand supply, of building codes to reduce costs, of infrastructure investment to enlarge the areas available for housing and retail facilities, and transport, to enhance mobility. There are two basic assumptions in housing policy in developed countries: The first is that home ownership is to be encouraged as it helps to stabilize social conditions in cities where people from different places and of different origins come together, and gives them an incentive to remain employed so as to keep their mortgages. The second is that housing policy should promote labour mobility, from regions of higher unemployment to places where firms are hiring. Both contributed to housing policies that steered governments toward treacherous financial shoals; both need to be re-examined in the light of experience. Home ownership strengthens social stability Measures to support home ownership were embedded in policies during the interwar period and during the years of rapid growth and rural-to-urban migration after World War Two, when competing socialist and communist ideologies exploited the fear that capitalism would keep workers in a permanent underclass, ill-housed and ill-clothed. Home ownership does not bring with it the benefits that made it a keystone in social policy for generations (The Economist, 2009) but it continues to influence fiscal policies on mortgage payments, and helped to justify the massive influence of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac in the United States. In its 2007 survey of the economy of the United States, the OECD wrote that “the accumulation of debt has been encouraged by the long-standing U.S. policy to promote housing. Governments have used a variety of instruments for this purpose[…]. While there seems to be socioeconomic benefits stemming from increased home ownership, the efficacy of these policy instruments in promoting homeownership is subject to controversies in the literature” (OECD, 2007). The Housing and Governance . Konvitz survey cites four tax breaks to homeowners: the income derived from housing service (net imputed rent) is not taxed; homeowners can exclude up to $250,000 ($500,000 for a married couple filing jointly) of capital gains on the sale of real property; full deductibility of mortgage interest payments on debt for a primary or secondary residence on up to $1 million in acquisition debt and up to $100,000 in home equity debt; and deductibility of local real estate taxes from federal income tax. As a result, the rate of taxation of housing is close to zero, and in some cases negative. These tax expenditures come at a large cost to the budget: the President’s Tax Reform Panel identifies incentives for homeownership as the second larges tax expenditure (after health deductions), with a total cost of over $700 billion during FY2006-07 excluding the non-taxation of imputed rent (another $185 billion). Lenders took advantage of these fiscal breaks, lowering lending standards significantly: in 2001, only 8% of home purchases had a down payment of zero, but by 2007 this figure had risen to 22% (OECD, 2011, p.186). Given the low savings rate in the United States, the housing boom was partly fuelled by foreign capital, and triggered a reallocation of resources from tradable goods to construction, “potentially weakening the competitive position”. Normal mechanisms for adjustment simply have not operated in recent years: it would be surprising if inflows of funds which ended up in housing were driven by a search for the most profitable investment opportunities! (André, 2010). It is important to grasp the scale of this annually recurring package, which contributed to an overheated housing market and left millions stranded with negative equity when the bubble burst, and which favours individuals with above-average incomes, in the light of the growing US deficit. This means not only that tax breaks and credit facilitation measures put in place by law for the express purpose of promoting homeownership have little effect on the propensity to own, but also that the benefits of homeownership are probably exaggerated, and in any case are difficult to disentangle from other factors such as educational opportunities that affect social mobility and lifestyle. these are not easy waters to navigate if only guided by a chart to steer away from the coastal enclaves of high-income residents who benefit most from the mortgage interest deduction, and toward the lowlands of the lower middle classes. A simulation of winners and losers from reform may reinforce an argument in favour of reform, but it won’t tell policymakers how to achieve it. Again the remedies in terms of tax and housing policy are clear, but the political means to achieve them are even further beyond the grasp of elected officials than they were in 1993, when the fiscal cost of these subsidies to households was a fraction of what it became in 2007. The findings of the OECD on housing tenure show that “home owners tend to be less mobile than private renters, even after taking into account other household characteristics (e.g., age and income, and marital, migrant and employment status, etc.)” (OECD, 2011, p.189). Why? Is this because homeowners face higher transaction costs than renters (a reason to measure those costs and re-regulate the conveyancing requirements and credit procedures)? Owners without a mortgage are estimated to be 13% less likely to move annually than private renters; by comparison, the annual mobility rate of owners with a mortgage is only 9% lower than that of renters. In other words, people with a mortgage may be in the housing market slightly more often than owners without one, perhaps because they are less likely to be retired, perhaps because they need to remain employed in order to keep up with mortgage payments. After decades of housing development in the United States (and elsewhere) based on single-family houses that are owner-occupied, access to schools, recreational facilities and even shopping is often a matter of “buying in”, acquiring a house within a given district. This is self-perpetuating: people may have no choice but to become owners, because other forms of tenancy do not provide equivalent access to the An April 2010 paper by Eric Toder, Margery Austin Turner, Katherine Lim and Liza Getsinger, Reforming the Mortgage Interest Deduction (Toder et al., 2010), compared the distributional effects of eliminating the mortgage interest deduction in different American regions, concluding that any of several tax credit options would benefit low-and middle-income groups, blacks and Hispanics, Midwestern metropolitan households and non-metropolitan households. But 11 Adam Smith Research Foundation . Working Papers Series services and amenities that they want. The roll-over of capital gains not he sale of a primary residence further reinforces home ownership, limiting consumer choice. There is evidence that the market does not reflect consumer preferences well enough. A recent report from Australia’s Grattan Institute highlight that people value both housing type and location, and that there is a mismatch, suggesting that there is greater potential for apartment buildings of 4 levels or more, and for semi-detached houses in the already built-up areas of central Melbourne and its inner suburbs. But financing for single-family dwellings on greenfield sites is easier to secure; lenders prefer a standard to an innovative product; and building and material costs will be lower for the house on a previously undeveloped land parcel. The case for government intervention can be made if there is the political will to make it – and the discipline to select instruments which will be least distorting, and easiest to remove or modify over time. Jane-Frances Kelly, “The Housing We’d Choose”, Report 2011-5, June 2011) Housing mobility reduces unemployment and improves resource allocation The second assumption concerns the impact of housing tenure and related regulatory measures on structural adjustment and unemployment. The argument is that when the nature of work changes, and when unemployment rises, a fluid housing market, one in which supply corresponds to demand and in which it is relatively easy to buy and sell property or to find adequate rental arrangements, promotes the redistribution of labor to regions or places where people can find work. This people-to-jobs strategy in a free market is reflected in the average of 6% of annual relocation characteristic of OECD countries as a whole. It is difficult to see how this can be part of the solution to the current economic crisis when people cannot so easily either buy or sell property. The macroeconomic logic of theory, to promote labour reallocation through housing policy to favor mobility, breaks down in reality. In countries with a strong, primary metropolitan region, there is less competition for workers with mobile and transferable skills than in a country with a more complex regional and urban structure. Language, religion, political orientations and other cultural and social variables affect residential choice. Rental tenancy should, from this point of view, be preferable to home ownership as long as rental arrangements do not lock people in to long-term leases, But in many countries such as 12 Australia and the US, rental housing is the secondbest option. On the one hand, renters are more likely to be unemployed, or to relocate to improve social and economic opportunities; but if renters are also more likely to be immigrants, or lack the resources to become home owners, they are precisely those groups who may need to be encouraged to buy property as a step toward social stability. Moreover, the glaring problems of social disengagement and alienation, once again high on the list of issues that governments must confront, are not primarily linked to poor quality housing or inadequate access to credit, but to the failures of government to coordinate the supply of public transport, vocational secondary education, and access to health care and environmental amenities at the neighborhood or district level. As the OECD pointed out in its 1998 report on distressed urban areas, unless complemented by more effective forms of intervention to improve them, a very fluid and flexible housing market will actually exacerbate patterns of spatial deprivation in large metropolitan areas, raising costs to society. Disparities within metropolitan areas can be as acute as those between fast-growing and declining regions. The challenge is to adopt low-cost means of enhancing accessibility, to reduce the social as well as physical distance between where people live and where they work by adopting area-based forms of coordination, to find solutions that people can use in their daily lives. Yet the hold of these assumptions, the first on the public and politicians, and the second on economists, is hardly shaken – yet. The sense of security that comes with homeownership, including forced savings and the opportunity for capital gain in anticipation of retirement later in life, remains strong, and does not appear to be affected when fiscal measures to encourage homeownership are withdrawn. Encouraging people to relocate remains rooted in a historical phase that is largely over in developed countries, a period of help-wanted signs posted on factory gates and in the advertising sections of newspapers, of a workforce of generic skills such that little on the job training is necessary, and of a sharp decline in the workforce employed in agriculture and living in the country. The combination of policies to promote homeownership and mobility made sense at a time when in a two-person household, one income could suffice; and it made sense when people did not have significant restrictions on mobility in the form of health benefits, pension rights, and the like. Housing and Governance . Konvitz There is an obvious way to see how these two assumptions are often coupled, and why the coupling is flawed: areas of high unemployment are often areas where housing costs relatively less than areas where there are more jobs, and more better-paying jobs. But the transfer of people from the one to the other does not clear housing or labour markets: lower housing prices are not sufficient to turn these areas around. The rustbelt of the US, eastern Canada, northern England, eastern Germany – the examples can be multiplied. The movement of people to areas where employment is growing can lead to locally overheated housing markets and to popular resistance to alter housing policies to accommodate population growth. The macroeconomic recommendation to increase supply is politically difficult, and int he best of circumstances, takes years to show effects. This is clearly a middle class issue. OECD analysis does not screen for national or regional differences, but interesting new research from France shows that the effect of the crisis of 2008 combined with the high cost of housing in Paris and the limited availability of quality rental properties in many smaller towns where there may be jobs are depressing relocations. A national survey on living conditions for the employers federation Medef, showed that 70% of those employed would turn down a professional opportunity if that involved a move which would increase their housing expense, calculated not only to include the cost of housing but also the cost of transport to work. The survey concluded that 500,000 people had refused a job opportunity over the last five years for this reason, and that people who owned their housing were overwhelmingly likely to take this decision, much more so than renters (Le Monde, 2011). If this trend is substantiated elsewhere, it hints at a new normative pattern which further undermines the assumption that housing mobility is key to reducing unemployment: we may be in a new equilibrium. generations, sometimes unwillingly, sometimes under compulsion, but often in pursuit of political freedom as well as economic opportunity. But migration is not the only or best solution for many. In a logic based on population mobility, cities try to capture jobs, to retain or attract people. They also try to make it more difficult for people who are likely to need expensive social services to stay put. Moreover, governments are concerned that too many people want to live in only a few places, leading to other problems for service delivery both within large, dense metropolitan regions, and in the rest of the country. The point is not to make housing markets less fluid, but to question how much they contribute to adjusting labour markets. There is a strong case to revise regulations that make transactions unnecessarily costly and time-consuming without resorting to arguments about labour resource allocation. The challenge is strengthen the link between firms and territories, to develop a form of stability for both, with reciprocal benefits. This goal, to lift overall output by developing the assets of all regions, is also part of the OECD policy toolkit for regional policy. That there is a tension between place-based regional and a-spatial macroeconomic policy simply reflects two different approaches to enhancing performance and the efficiency of public intervention. We will see which is better suited to the future. From the macroeconomic perspective, the best counter-argument could be that housing policy, based on improving economic opportunities where people live (rather than relying on mobility), will achieve an acceptable – and perhaps a better – allocation of resources. The reality is that most people relocate infrequently over a lifetime, and often stay within the same region when they do so. Moving is widely recognized to be among the most stressful experiences of life, nearly as severe as coping with death in the immediate family. Overall statistics The neo-classical solution of people-to-jobs, to increase “mobility by making housing supply more responsive and lowering purchase transaction costs”, does not take into account either the time it takes to bring about the necessary regulatory changes to improve mobility even if that were the desired outcome, or the likelihood that the crisis will itself generate a new pattern of unemployment and smaller households. The growth of cities in the 19th and 20th centuries has been a demonstration of the positive effects of mobility unique in the history of mankind: no other socio-economic experiment has been pursued by so many millions, across the 13 Adam Smith Research Foundation . Working Papers Series about how many people change residence annually mask the fact that some people change locations far more often than others. Building urban areas on the assumption that relocation or settlement should be easy has implications for the design of housing. In the logic of mobility, the more places resemble each other, with similar housing markets, schools and retail facilities, the easier it will be for people to relocate. The neo-classical approach to change, which would move people to jobs, can lead to a situation of precipitous decline in some places and unmanageable growth elsewhere. What does it cost to develop more sustainable territories? Or put another way, what is the cost to firms of weaker territories? What are the consequences when cities put short-term economic objectives ahead of medium-term social and environmental goals? And what can take the place of the strong belief, embedded in structural reform policies, that the solution to the mis-allocation of resources are migration and labour mobility? Wouldn’t it make more sense to look at place-based development positively, and align housing markets and policies accordingly? A jobs-to-people strategy assumes that localities have an adequate endowment in human and social capital, that investment is not distorted by subsidies and fiscal incentives, that administrative procedures (“red tape”) keep barriers to entry low and enable access to land and utilities, and that environmental and transport policies allow for under-developed or under-utilised assets to be re-developed. Admittedly this is a complex policy package, but evidence from countries as diverse in the OECD as Sweden, Switzerland, Mexico and Korea show how the right policies can be designed and implemented. The Middle Class and the Political Economy of Reform Everything that has been said up to this point has highlighted the critical status of the middle class in a public culture that increasingly facilities and promotes public participation, and is suspicious if not intolerant of top-down decisions taken without public consultation. Building a constituency for reform is critical to the success of any reform strategy, and perhaps more so for structural reforms which affect each household’s economic opportunities. Parliamentary democracy, the expansion of the suffrage and active participation in public affairs have been associated with the growth of a middle class 14 with a high level of social capital, a commitment to education, and a willingness to adopt innovations. But its optimism has been undermined, evident in indicators of declining trust in government across a variety of countries with different growth rates over the past two decades. Reforms of policy instruments in the housing sector which could reduce community control - the thrust of proposals affecting zoning, design standards, density, land use and construction permits - would be all the more difficult to adopt through a process which promotes and demands public participation. The ratio of incomes to housing prices has deteriorated, making it difficult for many younger people to enter the market to buy, and pushing owners to take on more debt when they do buy: household debt represented one year of disposable income in 1995 in OECD countries, 120% in 2000, but 170% in 2007 – levels which national governments reach at their peril. The long-term trend in price-to-income ratio in 7 countries exceeded 150 (when the long-term trend has a value of 100) (André, 2010, p.10). As borrowing constraints were alleviated, people enjoyed easier access to credit, without fully understanding the downside risks. Thus, the percentage of people who believed that prices would continue to rise kept increasing, even after the objective conditions to sustain such a belief began to come undone (p.24). No wonder that household debt increased dramatically, from about one year of household disposable income in 1995 to 120% in 2000 and close to 170% by 2007 (pp.21-22). Massive changes in the position of countries from debtor to creditor status, or vice-versa, have historically been associated with the most significant geo-political realignments: typically, wars and revolutions, or the gain or erosion of an empire. (This involves the expansion of the housing market in China’s cities just as much as it does the asset boom in the US or Australia.) These are metaevents which overwhelm individuals, and alter, at least for several decades, the larger horizons of what they consider possible. A rapid transformation of this kind within a population – with all it implies for national imbalances – is evocative of a change of values and behavior that is harder for people to understand because averages mask huge differences within communities, leading to a stronger sense of unfairness in the distribution of gains and losses. The opportunity to change behavior and expectations is there in countries where housing values have declined. People who acted as if prices would always rise have learned that home ownership does not Housing and Governance . Konvitz “purchase” security. But memories that affect behavior fade after a few years, and except for traumatic events – the great depression, for example, or hyperinflation – are unlikely to be embedded in the outlook of successive generations. Will the crash of 2008 and its after-effects fade, or persist? And what would be the consequences if its effects continued to influence public and private consumption and investment? In other words, the bias in behavior to invest in property as something more secure than other instruments for capital appreciation is likely to persist, and may in fact be reinforced by the excesses of financial deregulation and the sheer unintelligibility of financial instruments that it generated. “Many Americans Fear U.S. Living Standards Have Stopped Rising; They Believe Their Children Face a Tougher Future”, ran the headline of The Wall Street Journal, not in 2009, but twenty years earlier. In an ironic twist, and perhaps an unconscious one, the article appeared on 1st May – a day celebrated worldwide except in the United States and Canada as Labor Day. Eighteen months later, The Economist published a survey on American living standards, “Running to Stand Still” (1990). “I do not remember a time, not even during the ghastly ‘60s”, wrote Alistair Cooke, whose observations on America go back to the 1940s, “when Americans have complained more, in a tone close to despair, about the visible and seemingly unhealable wounds in American society[…], daily life, in every sort and size of community, is getting more squalid, expensive and dangerous” (Cooke, 1991). This was written in 1991, not 2011 when the political effects of inequality and polarization had tightened not only in the United States but in many western democracies where the centre no longer governed. (See also the article by Edward Luce, “Goodbye, American Dream”, (Financial Times, 2010), ironically in the same edition as an interview with Alan Greenspan in retirement.) shaped by trends reflected in public opinion that the victory in the Cold War, although it owed much to the western economic model, like the end of World War One, had not delivered an economic benefit. Trends that are the frequent subject of columnists since 2008 reflect concerns that were already manifest twenty years before: the slow growth of the earnings of American male workers; the likelihood for many that their children will do less well; and that housing and a college education, those two key features of middleclass families in the post-war era that appeared to explain and also symbolize the advance of America on the rest of the world, were less likely to repay the investment they absorb. The question is not, how accurate the assessments of 1989 or 1991 were, but how the sense of fear and insecurity takes hold in societies where people no longer trust government. Living standards have remained as high as before but at the price of heavier borrowing and higher spending. How can the situation be unwound when productivity can only be increased through greater investment in education, the environment and technology? The issues were just as clear in 1989 as in 2011. But the level of debt that has to be reduced or carried forward is considerably greater today, and the pressures on competitiveness in a globalised world are more intense. Why bring up the issue of the middle class squeeze? Without middle class support, the politics for reform in the housing sector remain elusive at best. The insecurity of the middle class shifts the politics of reform away from rebuilding fundamentals and toward reassurance of existing measures of social protection. Any package of reforms, combining reforms of housing finance and taxation, tenure contracts and rent regulations, land use and zoning rules and objectives, environmental policies and the modernization and extension of infrastructure and In 1990 it was clear that stagnation was distributed unequally: 80 % of the families in America knew what it meant, but the top fifth increased their percentage of the nation’s wealth. There were more two-income families, but these faced higher living costs and more expenses, not surprising in a country where the number of registered paid lobbyists in the United States Senate had increased from 365 in 1960 to 33,704 thirty years later, or 337 per senator. (A comparable figure concerns the number of lawyers: 260,000 in 1960, but 765,000 in 1990, in a country whose population had barely doubled). The run-up to the 1992 Presidential election in the United States was 15 Adam Smith Research Foundation . Working Papers Series transportation services will have to persuade the middle class that the future can be better and safer. What Could Be the Future Housing Policy? The picture is admittedly bleak: a prolonged housing slump, stranding millions of owners with negative equity, inhibiting family choices about employment, marriage or divorce, whether to have children, how to care for ageing parents; the reconversion of unemployed construction workers; deferred maintenance especially of rental properties; continued banking balance-sheet fragility; and a banking sector adverse to lending for imaginative projects. Municipalities will be hard-pressed to maintain the current level of property taxes in real terms, leading to difficult decisions about which services to maintain, which to cut, and which to provide for a fee. And housing prices will remain high in the large, global cities such as Paris, London and New York reflecting demand from foreigners seeking financial and political diversification, and from a small number of high-end, competitive professional sectors. In which western nation is there a people who believe that their communities will be better places to live and work in 10 years? The tensions between regions characterized by stagnant or rising property markets will weigh on national governments when considering interest rates, fiscal policy and visas for non-citizens. Can this policy mess be untangled? The point of departure is to recognize that the market is unlikely to generate a breakthrough, internalizing social costs and especially those associated with the risks of doing things differently today and tomorrow. The short-term dynamic driven by credit cycles obliges house-builders to bring to market the volume and style of product that can be expected to sell. The sale of new houses therefore reinforces the belief that the market supply of houses closely matches consumer preferences. But many people make choices within tight time frames, taking account of many variables such as access to recreational or educational facilities, commuting patterns, outdoor amenities, neighborhood security and the like which already limit his search to particular areas: in other words housing is very much a matter of compromises. The challenge lies in finding ways that blend a liberal approach to economic change with the social and environmental concerns of people in the places where they live. Now and for the foreseeable future, cities need to exploit their place-based assets, the 16 physical and immaterial qualities that can help attract jobs to the people that businesses want to employ. After all, most people do not move. A ‘jobs to people’ strategy engages macro-economic policy in a debate about whether place-based development can raise overall output rather than merely shift investment and employment from one place in decline to another which is growing. This is where strategic spatial planning becomes critical – not restrictive, predictive planning which freezes the status quo, but a creative exercise to identify the assets of places and to enhance their potential. As a form of strategic insight, it helps gives policy makers and the public a range of options and some insight into the consequences that could follow. Its task is to exert influence by framing ways of translating intentions into reality, mobilising many actors, leveraging investment. It cannot escape from the problems of policy coherence, the obstacles to implementation, the inherited professional specialisations, the lack of multi-year and multisectoral budgets, the different timeframes of public and private sector decision-makers. But perhaps it can contribute to solutions that transcend them (OECD, 2006, pp.135-6). If I am right, that a direct approach to reform housing policies at the macro and micro levels will not advance, even when supported by arguments in favour of growth and employment, then a different agenda, appealing to the middle class and its demand for security combined with community development, should be given consideration. Housing is linked to three of the most important issues facing government and society – how to accommodate an ageing population with its specific needs without segregating people by age; how to promote green growth when construction, as an activity, is energy-intensive, and when the built housing stock is responsible for significant recurring impacts on the use of energy and resources; and how to guide development to places where the risks of disasters are low, and to cope with reconstruction when disasters occur. Policies and strategies that mobilize private investment in relation to one or more of these objectives will help restore housing to a sustainable path by working with long-term trends. A suggestive overview should be sufficient to lift the reader’s vision, drawing attention away from detailed articles about loan-to-value ratios, the deductibility of mortgage interest payments, and the pressure on local governments that comes with a collapse in housing prices. Structural and regulatory reforms aligned with these policy objectives may be more likely Housing and Governance . Konvitz to attract political support than reforms grounded in macroeconomic theory, which is too remote front he preoccuptions and interests of people int he cities where they live. 1. Ageing, from the macro-economic perspective, is a question of how to leverage the stored value of homeownership to provide for housing and care. Instruments exist and more will be invented as the market grows. But the postwar baby-boomers now entering retirement, and perhaps their children in 2-3 decades, cannot so confidently expect a rising level of benefits as their parents enjoyed. At the very least this augurs ill: a return to the time when a rising percentage of the elderly fell back into poverty, or at least to a lower standard of living. Independence and self-reliance for the elderly will be as important to people in the middle class aged 25-55 as to their parents; the alternative, the multi-generational household, has already returned due to the circumstances facing young people (delayed marriage, unemployment, etc.); it could again be a pattern that marks advancing years. Financing is important, but there is the risk that a focus on innovative financing methods is simply a way to push the problem of sustainable housing solutions for an ageing population onto the population at large. Government interventions that go far beyond tax credits, legal changes that permit people to withdraw equity without affecting the rights of inheritors, etc. will be needed. The challenges for housing for an ageing population include: adapting dwelling units so that people can stay in them even as their physical and mental conditions alter; maintaining contact at the local level and across distances, including the use of tele-communications and video; convenient and accessible transport for people; and arranging housing to promote social interaction including across generations. Local cultural and socio-economic circumstances will dictate particular solutions, but innovative methods to renovate housing (or even to build housing so that it is suitable to people as they age), and of the financing to cover the costs, will bear international, cross-cultural comparison. usually positive. In one sense it is nothing new: a conservative use of resources is always to be preferred to waste. What then is distinctive about green growth? First, that the parameters and targets can and will be measured, with indicators that can be disaggregated down to the level of the individual household and aggregated upwards to large metropolitan areas. Individual efforts will be necessary to achieve collective results. In terms of housing, this will call for extensive renovations to the existing stock, new designs and technologies for new buildings which in turn will need renovation over time to remain state-of-the-art, monitored construction and waste treatment operations, integrated transport-housing strategies, and much more. The transition from established city-building practices to new standards and procedures, will itself generate economic activity. Green growth will affect public procurement, trade in urban goods and services, and employment, of course positively in the eyes of those who promote it. Because different parts of a metropolitan area call for different degrees of change, and because the costs and benefits of change will vary accordingly, the investments for green growth will have implications for the perceived value of individual properties and neighborhoods. New governance arrangements for green growth management will be needed as well. And existing tax arrangements affecting housing and public service investment will need to be re-examined. 3. Risk, the third challenge, is closer to the management of rights. The emergence of the gated community or enclave, and the spread of passive tele-surveillance technologies, are symptomatic of the demand for security, but also of its political and social costs. At the very 2. Green growth is one of those elusive terms that means different things to different people, 17 Adam Smith Research Foundation . Working Papers Series least, they speak of the felt need to identify with a place, and to live in a place with an identity. Anything that threatens this is perceived as a threat to the community, and weakens trust in government. People have a right to be protected against known risks with catastrophic potential, and to be assisted should a catastrophe occur. This is why states possess legal powers that allow governments to prevent construction in flood plains or in zones prone to devastating fires, to force relocations under certain conditions, and to suspend the operation of certain rules and obligations during an emergency, and impose others. A comprehensive view would look at building codes, neighborhood design, land-use planning, insurance, enforcement and compliance. We know that people are notoriously poor judges of the risks to which they are actually exposed; that emergency services often prove to be chronically deficient when asked to perform; that governments at all levels are ill-prepared to reconstruct a territory that has been badly damaged or destroyed in a catastrophe; that governments are reluctant, to say the least, to re-shape the settlement pattern of a region in the light of new evidence that the risks of a disaster are far greater than had previously been believed; and that popular enthusiasm to do things differently, which is so strong in the immediate after-effects of a crisis, abates quickly. Providing a reasonable level of protection against social disorder and environmental disaster was the responsibility of the medieval commune; why not of the modern metropolis? All three policy challenges also involve major infrastructure commitments – but usually these are seen as separate from housing policy. Infrastructure embodies a vision of how space can be organized, and therefore of opportunities to capitalize on change, lifting the economy in ways that return significant dividends in the form of more efficient labour markets, higher levels of social and human capital. Infrastructure investment can be mobilized, not just to improve annual maintenance, nor to simply extend capacity in existing networks for water, energy and transport, but to support new patterns of development within existing metropolitan regions. There is latent demand – underdeveloped land, regeneration sites, bottlenecks, social services and open spaces to be improved and enlarged. Each of the last three waves of metropolitan development since the 1880s has been characterized by the close – almost synchronous – development 18 of new housing patterns and infrastructure: 1880s1920s – streetcars and metropolitan railways put order into suburbs and supported the densification of urban cores with high-rise construction; the 1950s-70s witnessed the creation of urban and inter-urban highspeed road networks and of rapid regional transit, permitting dense urban nodes to develop on the urban periphery; and since the 1990s, the modernization of older forms of urban travel including streetcars and cycling, making inner-city living attractive as an alternative to further outward development at low density. Airports are now the largest employment nodes in metropolitan areas, but no one wants to live near them, posing significant questions about 24-hour transport services. Rather than define the next infrastructure-innovation-investment wave in terms of a single mode of transportation (canal, turnpike, railroad, automobile, airplane, container ship…), look instead at how different transport modes, technologies of control, and patterns of energy use will be articulated into specific local and regional systems. Taken together, the three imperatives – housing for an ageing population, green growth, and protection against disasters – imply changes in the fabric, scale and complexity of cities from the level of the individual neighborhood to that of the metropolitan region. In many cases this will lead to increased density and “compact cities”. But the emphasis should not be put on density as such – this can lead to narrow definitions and numerical targets – but rather to quality of life indicators and their elusive relation to economic performance. Places where the results can be seen first will enjoy “demonstration effects” much like Paris in the 1860s, Chicago or Berlin a generation later, New York at mid-century, followed by Los Angeles, and Tokyo. Is “paradigm shift” too strong a term? Is anything less likely to sustain the governance agenda needed to generate a recovery? All three policy challenges have significant implications for regulations that affect housing construction and markets. And all three have implications for spatial planning, especially to prepare cities to absorb change to the existing built environment. Combining all three policy challenges into a place-based approach will be a challenge for a generation, one equivalent to the mobilization of talent, initiative and investment that occurred after 1945 throughout the developed economies of the west. But it may take nothing less to compensate for the lack of vision and proactive policy today. The nature and rapid pace of change has always been uncertain, but there have been times when leaders in government, business and society Housing and Governance . Konvitz were more confident of the kind of future they wanted for their cities and regions. The utopian aspects of building new cities and suburbs can and should be transformed into the rebuilding of cities and suburbs for the society we have now and are likely to have for a few decades. Let the old city become the new, with more mixed use, more customized design, more specialized forms which take better account of the changing needs and wants of people for leisure, work and daily living. Conclusion Inertia has become a substitute for policy when difficult decisions with long-term consequences are needed. Construction contributed massively to the crash of 2008, with ramifications in many countries whose housing policies were apparently sound. We cannot build our way out of this recession, but we can set the foundations for a more sustainable pattern of urban development. In summary, what is needed, beyond a moratorium on proposals for micro reforms that fail to include sound work plans for implementation? • Forward-looking assessment of housing needs based on structural demographic trends; • A place-based approach that combines risk reduction and an integrated energy-watertransport planning; • Aggressive investment in research to develop the products, skills and designs for green growth in housing; review of regulations to promote the adoption and diffusion of innovations; • • Intensive application of the tools to assess and revise regulations at national and sub-national level, including in finance; ministers. The private sector won’t take the initiative, nor will communities more afraid of the future than satisfied with the present. Macroeconomic stability and other economic policy objectives have not been sufficient to generate reforms in housing policy; pragmatically, a different approach is necessary. Ageing, green growth and risk reduction , will help people anticipate the benefits of reform in terms they appreciate. When millions of people needed to be housed in the 20th century, ministers discovered the secret charms of housing policies that generated ribbon-cutting and spade-digging opportunities every week. Yet at hand is an equally compelling agenda to make housing policy politically attractive. Who will show the way? The regulatory governance gap in housing policy must be redressed. This paper began with the assertion that regulatory reform of both macro and micro instruments in housing policy is and will remain difficult, handicapped in part by the disconnect between regulatory policy and housing policy experts. It concludes with an agenda for reform and for a review of regulation which could support the dialogue that so far has been missing. m References André, C. (2010) A Bird’s Eye View of OECD Housing Markets, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 746, OECD Publishing. pp. 33, 41-42. <http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5kmlh5qvz1s4-en> Cooke, A. (1991) Financial Times, 5-6 October, Section II, pp.1-2. The Economist (1990) ‘Running to stand still’. 10 November. The Economist (2009) ‘Home Ownership.’ Briefing, April 18. A strong communications strategy linking good governance with policy substance and outcomes. Only a redirection of policy objectives will empower political leadership to address the multi-level and cross-sectoral governance challenges which handicap housing policy reform. Reforms that affect and are implemented by regional and local authorities must be synchronised with others that involve central ministries or even independent authorities. Co-ordination calls for results that cannot be achieved through the routine of committee meetings and tasks delegated to junior 19 Adam Smith Research Foundation . Working Papers Series Hayek, F.A. (1960) The Constitution of Liberty. University of Chicago Press. Luce, E. (2010) ‘Goodbye, American Dream’, The Financial Times, 31 July-1 August. McDonald, R., Forman, R. & Kareiva, P. (2010) ‘Open Space Loss and Land Inequality in United States Cities, 1990-2000’, PLoS ONE, 5(3): e9509. Mallach, A. & Vey, S.J. (2011) Recapturing Land for Economic and Fiscal Growth. Washington DC: Brookings-Rockefeller Project on State and Municipal Innovation. <http://www.brookings.edu/~/media/ Files/rc/papers/2011/0503_land_vaule_mallach_ vey/0503_land_value_mallach_vey.pdf> Le Monde (2011) ‘La flambee des prix de l’ immobilier freine la mobilite professionnelle et l‘emploi’, 28-29 August, p.11. OECD (2006) Competitive Cities in the Global Economy. OECD Territorial Reviews. pp. 135-36. <http://www.oecd.org/document/2/0,3746, en_2649_33735_37801602_1_1_1_1,00.html> OECD (2007) Economic Survey of the United States 2007. <http://www.oecd.org/document/51/0,2340, en_2649_34111_38626675_1_1_1_1,00.html> OECD (2008a) Land Use Restrictions as Barriers to Entry. DAF/COMP(2008)25. <http://www.oecd.org/ dataoecd/34/37/41763060.pdf> OECD (2008b) Competition in the Construction Industry. DAF/COMP(2008)36. <http://www.oecd.org/ dataoecd/32/55/41765075.pdf> OECD (2011) Economic Policy Reforms: Going for Growth 2011. <http://www.oecd.org/document/15/0,3746, en_2649_34325_47448207_1_1_1_1,00.html> Prokop, G., Jobstmann, H. & Schönbauer, A. (2011) Overview of Best Practices for Limiting Soil Sealing or Mitigating its Effects in EU-27: Final Report. Technical Report 2011-050. Brussels: European Commission. <http://ec.europa.eu/environment/soil/pdf/sealing/ Soil%20sealing%20-%20Final%20Report.pdf> Toder, E., Austin Turner, M., Lim, K. & Getsinger, L. (2010) Reforming the Mortgage Interest Deduction. Washington DC: Urban Institute/ What Works Collaborative/ Tax Policy Centre. <http://www.urban. org/uploadedpdf/412099-mortgage-deductionreform.pdf> m 20 Housing and Governance . Konvitz 21 Adam Smith Research Foundation College of Social Sciences University of Glasgow 66 Oakfield Avenue Glasgow G12 8LS Tel: +44 (0)141 330 7656 / 3494 email: adamsmith-asrf@glasgow.ac.uk www.glasgow.ac.uk/asrf © University of Glasgow 2011 The University of Glasgow, charity number SC004401
© Copyright 2025 Paperzz